RUSSIA: PRIMAKOV'S ECONOMIC POLICY DILEMMA AND U.S. INTERESTS

CRS Report for Congress
Russia: Primakov’s Economic Policy Dilemma
and U.S. Interests
May 3, 1999
John P. Hardt
Senior Specialist in Post-Soviet Economics
Foreign Affairs, Defense, and Trade Division


Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

ABSTRACT
This report focuses on two divergent scenarios faced by Russia in the wake of its financial
crisis of August 1998. Prime Minister Yevgenii Primakov expected either a vicious cycle of
decline and possible collapse in government or an economic management scenario following
outlines of an agreed action program that makes imperative fundamental changes in the
Russian financial system. The success or failure of Russia in dealing with this crisis may have
more effect on the pursuit of peace and prosperity by the United States than any other foreign
policy crisis. This report draws on a number of CRS reports that summarize actions relevant
to United States relations with Russia, including CRS Report 98-578 E, The Russian
Financial Crisis: An Analysis of Trends, Causes and Implications; CRS Issue Brief 92089,
Russia; CRS Report 98-299 F, Russian Missile Technology and Nuclear Reactor Transfers
to Iran. This report builds upon CRS Report 97-977 E, Russia’s Opportunity to Enter a New
Stage of Transition. This report may be updated or superseded by a new report, dependingth


on action in the 106 Congress on these issues or events.

Russia: Primakov’s Economic Policy Dilemma and U.S.
Interests
Summary
Russia’s devaluation of the ruble and default on its debts in August 1998 put it
in its most serious crisis to date. If trends that created the crisis continue, Russia is
faced with a vicious downward cycle toward dire economic straits--hyperinflation,
steep reduction in output and income, default on debts precluding the ability to
borrow; political weakness--disintegration of central government power with
increased corruption and instability, and growing military dissent inviting a political
implosion resulting in a threatened collapse of Russia’s ability to govern. The Russian
government, foreign donors and investors agree that this is the likely outcome without
radical change. The Primakov government and the donors (International Monetary
Fund, the major industrial economies--the G-7, led by the United States) are
negotiating on an Action Program that might, if effectively implemented, provide a
basis for managing economic revival. Effectively dealing with debt management, bank
restructuring and reform, budget balancing, and investment generation might keep the
major donors and some investors engaged with the Russians and justify domestic
support of reform. Adjusting now, before the parliamentary and presidential elections
of December 1999 and June 2000, might open the option of proceeding toward
comprehensive reform in the manner of Poland and other successfully reforming
states.
The choices between the vicious cycle and managed economy are stark and
understandable to Russians and donors alike. However, the shortfalls in reform that
created the crisis also established the wealth and power of the financial industrial
groups, the oligarchs, who must change from “rent seekers” living off politically
determined allocations from the State budget and monopoly profits, to “profit
seeking” competitive groups able to contribute to economic growth, reduction of
poverty, and payment of taxes. This change is crucial to the success of a managed
economy scenario.
The United States has different policy options if either the vicious cycle or
managed economy scenario develops. Without concrete, fundamental measures by
the Russians, the United States and all major donors are committed to limiting support
to humanitarian aid and some military reduction programs. The United States may
in this negative scenario face a hostile Russia still armed with nuclear weapons that
is viewed by our defense authorities as the number one threat to our security. With
a successful Russian economic adjustment strategy, the United States may play a
major role in responding to Russian concrete reform actions leading all donors to
provide targeted assistance keyed to Russian actions and therefore likely to stimulate
foreign direct investment from the United States and elsewhere, especially in the
energy sector. If successful over time, Russia might then move toward becoming a
political ally in peacekeeping and a partner in development of some of the most
romising natural resources and technologically advanced assets in the world.



Contents
Russia’s Historic Turning Point.....................................1
A Primakov Action Program.......................................3
Past Reform Shortfalls: Remediation Essential for the Current Crisis.........5
Post-Crisis Scenarios and U.S. Policy Options..........................9
Broader U.S.-led Conditionality....................................13



Russia: Primakov’s Economic Policy Dilemma
and U.S. Interests
Russia’s Historic Turning Point
Resolution of post-Soviet Russia’s most serious economic crisis is of singular
importance to the United States. The danger to the United States of a failed Russian
Federation is great through possible deployment and use of nuclear and conventional
weaponry; increased destabilization of its Eurasian neighbors, possible return of
authoritarian governance of a weakened federation, and further aggravation of the
global economic crisis. On the other hand the opportunities opened by Russia’s
actively managing its crisis and keeping open the prospects of return to a democratic
market trend would provide positive benefits; a cooperative Russia moving toward
a democratic market system might become an important political ally and business
partner. Congressional interest has been expressed on monitoring the measures
promised by the Primakov government, which are intended to meet the challenges of
its financial crises and respond to the requirements of donors and investors. This
criticality of Russian-United States relations is illustrated by the importance attached
to its government's bilateral economic discussions with U.S. leaders and the relevance
of the Kosovo crisis and ratification of the Start II agreement to these exchanges.
Many Russian specialists in and outside Russia believe Russia is doomed to a
downward trend before the parliamentary and presidential elections in the months
ahead. Michael Marrese of Chase Manhattan Bank, London, reflects this widely held
view by projecting a “vicious cycle,” a deepening crisis of hyperinflation, increased1


capital flight and debt default as the most likely scenario for Russia. The vicious
Michael Marrese, Russia: Balanced Payments Deterioration and Capital Flight Equals1
Debt Servicing Blues, Chase Manhattan International Fixed Income Research, December 11,
1998. For detailed assessment of capital flight to date by Canadian and Russian economic
specialists, see The Problem of Capital Flight from Russia, A final report from a joint project
on capital flight from Russia undertaken by the Institute of Economics, Moscow, and The
Center for the Study of International Economic Relations, University of Western Ontario,
Canada, October, 1998; 37 pages. Philip Hanson, The Russian Economic Crisis and the
Future of Russian Economic Reform, draft paper for a meeting at SAIS, Johns Hopkins,
February 12, 1998; William Cooper, The Russian Financial Crisis: An Analysis of Trends,
Causes and Implications, CRS Report 98-578 E, February 18, 1999; Andrei Illarionov,
“Financial Crisis in Russia,” Institute of Economic Analysis, Moscow, September 1998;
Susan Gold, editor, “The Russian Economy in Crisis,” Harriman Review, December 1998,
31 pages; James Duran, The Russian Federation: Political and Economic Update, Atlantic
Council Bulletin, December 8, 1998; Keith Bush, “The Russian Economy in December
1998,” Center for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS), Washington, DC, August
(continued...)

cycle assessment is basically a projection of past trends that gave rise to the current
financial crisis.
When Yevgeni Primakov took the reins of government in September 1998, he
found Russia in its most serious economic crisis in its seven-year existence. With the
default on debts and devaluation of the ruble by the previous government on August
17, 1998, Primakov stated that his government needed to take urgent measures to
avoid defaulting on sovereign debt.
International donors and some investors adopted a policy of continued
engagement with Russia under which concrete measures must be taken by Russia to
receive further assistance--measures such as debt settlement, setting up a workable
monetary system, adopting and implementing a sound budget, and, most importantly,
establishing a rule of law for businesses to encourage investment. The new approach2
of requiring both Russian commitments and concrete measures as preconditions for
assistance resulted from donor perceptions that previous reform-oriented Russian
governments consistently made commitments that were not honored by performance.
Thus successful negotiations between the Primakov government and the donors are
premised on implementation of urgent, concrete measures that would redress the
critical problems that caused the financial crisis and keep open the option for future
transition to comprehensive reform after parliamentary elections in December 1999
or the presidential elections in June 2000.
The Russian reform record from September 1998 through March 1999 did not
change the views of many Primakov skeptics because concrete radical reform
measures were not implemented. Still, Primakov’s government has repeatedly
reaffirmed his assessment of the seriousness of its crisis and need for urgent measures
that seem to conform to conventional wisdom on the minimum requirements of an
incremental policy as judged by the global market, donors, and investors. The IMF
Managing Director Michel Camdessus and the Russian authorities agreed on key
elements of an economic program required to receive continued support from all
donors for 1999 and beyond.3


(...continued)1

1998; Michael Ellman and Robert Sharrenborg, “The Russian Financial Crisis and the IMF,”


Problems of Post-Communism, September-October 1998, pp. 17-25.
Lawrence Summers, Under Secretary of Treasury, testimony to Senate Foreign Relations2
Committee, January 27, 1999 following similar comments at Davos World Economic
meetings in December, 1998.
Camdessus and Russian Leaders Agreed on Key Elements of Economic Program, April 29,3
1999. “The program includes many measures in the fiscal, banking, and structural areas that
the authorities have undertaken to implement, including through enacting the necessary
legislation, as quickly as possible. The authorities have also agreed to provide me with a full
explanation of the management of reserves by the CBR [Central Bank of Russia] and the use
of disbursements from the IMF over the last few years.” [IMF Website]

A Primakov Action Program
The Russian government needs to implement measures that Primakov has
indicated would lead to promised improvements in output, reduced social tensions,
manageable inflation, a stronger central government, and effective debt service
management. These actions are needed to elicit foreign support. Successful reform
may also enhance Primakov’s chances to stay in office and later ascend to the
presidency.
!Preconditions for Successful Action Program. A two-step approach would
seem warranted for Primakov’s action program to be successful, judging by
actions and successful reforms elsewhere.

1) A Broad Activated Political Consensus Favoring His Economic Action Program.


A broadly based Russian program is necessary for success, including support of some
industrial magnates or oligarchs who favor globalization, market system
institutionalization, and a rule-driven society; and some regional governors who
would benefit from radical change and economic improvement; and some more of the
electorate who favor reform as a means to ensure a fairer, more efficient system with
prospects of improved performance. The Duma, Primakov’s original parliamentary
sponsor, might be influenced by all of the above. President Yeltsin is certainly a wild
card in developing and implementing a consensus-based policy.
2) Institutional Changes to Make the State Market Friendly. Establishment of a legal
and regulatory system through fiscal, monetary and military reform would be required
to create the necessary institutional infrastructure. This would especially require a
change in the power and mindset of key Russian entrepreneurs, the financial industrial
groups, and the oligarchs, who must change from “rent seekers” living off politically
determined allocations from the State budget and monopoly profits, to “profit
seeking” competitive groups able to contribute to economic growth, reduction of
poverty, and payment of taxes. As Primakov is aware, a broad political consensus
supporting reform and establishing an institutional infrastructure conducive to the
implementation of his action program is necessary for successful reform and support4
by donors. The recent weakening of recalcitrant oligarchs such as Boris Berezovsky
may indicate that this change is taking place.
!Implementation of an Action Program.
1) Debt rescheduling. Discussion on restructuring and renegotiating the debt
inherited by Russia from the Soviet Union is under way for commercial debt (London
Club) and sovereign debt (Paris Club). Russians would like the London Club and
Paris Club debt to be generously restructured and rescheduled, using the precedents
of the Polish debt rescheduling of 1990-92. It may be essential for all debts, not just
sovereign debts, to be restructured with substantial long-term forgiveness and front-
loaded relief on servicing. Other concrete measures toward comprehensive Russian


Nicholas Stern, The Transition in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union: The4
Strategic Lessons from the Experience of 25 Countries over Six Years, Working Paper No.

18, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1997.



reform would be critical to creditors’ acceptance of deep debt restructuring. The
initial problem for the Russian government is to meet the $17.5 billion debt servicing
required for 1999 with only half that amount available from their own budget. With
revenue projected this year at $22 billion, Russia would have to use 80 percent of its
budget for debt servicing. Therefore assurance that as much as $9 billion would be
covered by successful negotiations is critical. Moreover the first debtor in the queue
is the IMF, with some $4.6 billion due. IMF agreement to begin releasing funds to
Russia in May, 1999 is a critical first step. Successful negotiations on debt reduction
and repayment schedules acceptable to both sides will be necessary to avoid default.
Primakov has frequently reassured creditors that all debts would be repaid, albeit after
restructuring.
2) Commercial and Central Bank Restructuring. The restructuring and
recapitalization of the paralyzed banking system, funded by state finances, would
result in many banks going bankrupt. Recapitalized banks would need to be guided
by sound banking practices in order to begin to generate more savings and investment.
Russian and Western financial interests would have to accept substantial losses and
recapitalized banks would need to be covered by new monetary regulations and legal
requirements. The Central Bank of Russia would need to become more transparent5
and accountable for reserves and play an effective regulatory role for commercial
banks. Bank restructuring is projected to be completed by summer 1999 under a
program set up by the Primakov government. An effective banking reform process
might then result in foreign banks accepting Primakov's invitation to operate in
Russia. Another critical indicator of trust in banking reform would be the willingness
of the oligarchs to pull their still substantial financial assets back from abroad for
deposit in their own banks, and Russian citizens' willingness to take some $40 billion
in assets out of their mattresses, and to deposit them in Russian banks.
3) Budget Balancing. State and regional budgets need to make progress toward
supporting necessary expenditures from central, state, and regional revenues without
incurring an additional debt burden. Under the agreed guidelines of the Primakov
IMF agreement March 29, 1999, a new, fairer, and more efficient tax code might be
passed into law and implemented with a new budget, e.g., reducing the burden on
legal enterprises and increasing the yield from the value added tax. Institutional
reforms, including military and administrative reforms would be necessary to cut
excessive expenditures and eliminate the carryover nomenklatura state6
administrators. Moving toward budget balancing illustrates the complementary or
synergistic character of the action program: the debt service burden on the state
budget would be reduced by debt renegotiation; banking reform might reduce the
budget subsidies for failing banks; and increased foreign investment and related joint
ventures may lead to increases in tax revenue and other financial flows to the state
treasury.


European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), Financial Sector in5
Transition, November 1998. John P. Hardt, Russian Banking System: Facilitation or
Barrier to Investment-Based Growth, CRS Memorandum to Russia Watchers December 17,

1997. 10 pages.


Hardt, CRS Report 97-977 E, op. cit.6

4) Foreign Direct Investment Generation. Market-friendly laws, including an
implemented civil code, would encourage foreign direct investment. Full and viable
production-sharing agreements for joint energy ventures would have immediate utility
if they begin to meet the need for assured foreign investor return on investment.
While passage of new production-sharing laws is necessary, their implementation with
approval for opening some of the more profitable fields to joint ventures would be
necessary to lead to the often-predicted double-digit, billion-dollar U.S. investment
in Russian energy resources. Primakov has complained that U.S. and other foreign
investors have favored other Central Eastern European countries in placing their
investments. Russian Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) was one-tenth of per-capita
financial flows to Hungary in 1997 and only 0.8 percent of Russian Gross Domestic
Product (GDP). Increased FDI is critical to coping with the financial crisis. In
addition to financial flows, FDI would provide advanced technology and managerial
and a corporate governance culture of market economies to Russian enterprises. FDI
is also a non-debt-creating source of current account finance. A steady flow of FDI
is an important sign of confidence since the world's major credit rating agencies
include it among their indicators of international creditworthiness: thus, a rising inflow
of FDI can help to create a “virtuous circle” in which improved creditworthiness leads
to more FDI.
Past Reform Shortfalls: Remediation Essential for the
Current Crisis
In spite of some success in stabilization, liberalization, and privatization in the

1992-1998 period, critical shortfalls in reform policy set the economy on a course7


toward financial crisis. Past failures reduced effectiveness of reform efforts from

1992-1998:


by continued subsidization of unproductive security forces and bureaucracy;
by permitting wealth creation that was channeled abroad and for consumption
of newly wealthy elite rather than into productive investment and tax revenues;
by privatization without restructuring that would have created competitive
enterprises generating economic growth and state revenues;
and, by imprudent short-term financing by sales of government securities that
inflated the debt-servicing burden in the budget and led to the default in August, 1998.
Addressing these past failures and reform shortfalls is critical in the
implementation of the Primakov Action program for dealing with the current crisis.


Anders Aslund, “Social Problems and Policy in Postcommunist Russia,” in Ethan B.7
Kapstein and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., Sustaining the Transition: The Social Safety Net
in Poscommunist Europe, Council on Foreign Relations, New York: 1997, pp. 124-146;
Anders Aslund and Mikhail Dmitriev, “Economic Reform: Reform versus Rent-Seeking,” in
Russia After Communism, Anders Aslund and Martha Olctott, eds., Washington, DC:
Carnegie, Chapter four (forthcoming, 1999).

!Retention and Expansion of Security Forces and Bureaucracy operating under
old inefficient rules of the game. The failure to downsize and restructure
Russia’s security forces and administrative bureaucracy puts a heavy burden
on the state budget and has been an incentive to inefficiency and corruption.
The heritage and continued burden of the Soviet militarized system contributed
to the current crisis. The precipitous decline and erratic financing of military forces
led, by 1995, to an escalating crisis in the formerly preferred military forces and the
military-industrial complex. In 1997 Yegor Gaidar, chairman of the budgetary
advisory committee to the last government, noted:
The chief national threat for the country is not the expansion of NATO to the east,
but its own unreformed, hungry and disgruntled army and the economy can no
longer withstand the financial load of maintaining an overstaffed and amorphous
army. It hurts that military reform is starting too late. Much time has been lost.8
Better late than never.
Military reform is to date considered “crisis management rather than managed
restructuring,” according to the International Institute of Strategic Studies (IISS). In
spite of Russia’s large and burdensome budget, the IISS estimates the true level of
military spending at about 27 percent of federal budget or 7 percent of gross domestic
product when the cost of paramilitary forces, arms control and subsidies to military9
regions and industries are included.
The central administrative civilian bureaucracy has doubled since 1991 to 1.2
million, operating within much the same ministerial system as the old regime, despite
the fact that the Russian Federation has half the population of the former Soviet
Union. Regional administrations have also retained much of the old system’s10
structure and operating procedures. The present state system is not only inefficient
but is acknowledged to breed corruption. In Russia an estimated 30-40 percent of the
senior enterprise manager’s time is estimated to be spent in dealing with the state
officials, whereas in market economies the time averages only 8-12 percent. By
international comparisons, Russia’s state administration ranks with Nigeria, Bolivia,
and Colombia as most prone to corruption. 11
A good deal of the promise of the earlier reform teams was that they had taken
over many of the leadership positions in the central government ministries and
institutions, e.g., finance, economics, energy, privatization and the central bank, with


Yegor Gaidar, RIA Novosti, May 23, 1997; Clifford G. Gaddy, The Price of the Past,8
Russia's Struggle with the Legacy of a Militarized Economy, Brookings Institution, 1996;
Stuart Goldman, CRS Report 97-820, Russian Conventional Armed Forces: On the Verge
of Collapse? 54 pages.
The Military Balance 1997/98, International Institute of Strategic Studies, London, October9

1997.


John P. Hardt, op. cit., CRS Report 97-977 E.10
Paolo Mauro, “The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment and Government11
Expenditure: A Cross Country Analysis,” in Kimberly Ann Elliott, ed., Corruption and the
Global Economy, Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1997.

their own reform-minded staff in key positions. The chief economist of the World
Bank argues that a new state in transition from command to market systems needs to
do more than to change top managers; it needs to be characterized by public-private
partnerships that ensure that contracts are enforced and that expansion of markets into
such areas as education, health, and pensions are both equitable and efficient. 12
!Non-Productive Wealth Generation Limiting Productive Investment and Tax
Revenue. In 1992 over three-quarters of the Gross Domestic Product was
channeled to wealth creation that did not contribute to investment or state
revenue and instead weakened the value of the ruble and the balance of
payments. Due to weakness in state regulation and politically controlled
benefits, substantial fortunes were built up, e.g., by buying oil at very low
domestic prices and selling at the world market price, by buying consumer
goods including food at competitive foreign prices and selling at subsidized
internal prices, and by obtaining “soft” bank loans for which repayment was
not enforced. This exploitation diminished over successive years, but some
such rent-seeking and monopoly profits continued up to the financial crisis.13
The newly rich oligarchs channeled much of their wealth abroad, motivated by
the classical reason for capital flight, fear of losing their assets. Capital flight
has been estimated by an authoritative Canadian-Russian study to have been
between $125-$140 billion in the years 1991-1997. A Western banker14
estimates capital flight at $20 billion in 1998 and projects $17.1 billion for

1999 if trends continue.15


!Privatization Without Restructuring of Enterprises. In 1993 and early 1994
transfer of state assets by voucher privatization and in 1997 loans for shares
at low cost to some politically influential rent seekers further reduced the
effectiveness of reform by directing financial flows away from new capital
assets for generating new output and shifting revenue away from the state
budget. Those who benefitted from the wealth-generating opportunities of
1992 and others in politically advantageous positions were able to gain control
of some of the most valuable industrial assets at low prices in the voucher
privatization. The financial industrial groups, formed by those newly rich with
ownership of key industries and banks, also gained control of key media
sources--newspapers, TV and radio stations. When seeking reelection in 1997,
President Yeltsin turned to them for financial and political support and offered
shares in other key state enterprises as security for their financial support.
Thus the “loans for shares” program extended the oligarchs’ control. Had


Joseph E. Stiglitz, More Instruments and Broader Goals: Moving Toward a Post-12
Washington Consensus, World Institute for Development Economic Research, Helsinki,
January 1998.
Anders Aslund, Why Has Russia’s Economic Transformation Been So Arduous? Paper13
prepared for the World Bank’s Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics,
Washington, DC, April 28-30, 1999.
Canadian-Russian Capital Flight Study, op. cit.14
Marrese, op. cit. Russian Central Bank Chairman Gerashchenko provided a $40 billion15
figure for 1998 and a $200 billion estimate for total capital flight.

privatization been undertaken through open auctions with foreign and domestic
bidders, the state would have received much-needed cash, and the enterprises
might have been restructured to make them competitive and profitable. This
openness was the pattern followed in successful transitions and privatizations
in Hungary and Poland.
The reform shortfall in voucher privatization and loans for shares programs was
that Russian privatization did not lead to restructuring the capital assets and
management of Russian enterprises. The new enterprise owners reinforced the power
of the rent-seeking oligarchs, who benefitted from their influence on the state
bureaucracy and access to the state budget. Restructuring the physical assets and
management system of the enterprises in the most militarized economy in history has
been a most formidable challenge not yet met by the reform program. Although some
political gains may have accrued from reduction in state ownership, the privatization
process that followed reinforced the rent-seeking rather than the profit-seeking
criteria for success, and set back the monetization of the economy. The newly rich
oligarchs were in a strong position to extract rents through political influence on the
government and by operating outside the official economy. Many less politically
powerful found that operating outside the official economy favored their survival.
Over half of the transactions in Russia may have been in the barter or virtual economy16
rather than in the official economy. The barter or virtual sector is a survival
economy whose industrial enterprises do not contribute to economic growth and do
not provide tax revenue to the state budget. Moreover, the banks privatized without
state regulation do not perform their primary function of providing capital to
restructured and new enterprises. Russian privatization, stabilization, and
liberalization were necessary changes. They were not alone sufficient to ensure
introduction of the profit motive and economic growth because the Russian economy
lacked the necessary systemic infrastructure. Joseph E. Stiglitz, Chief Economist of
the World Bank, aptly summarized the shortfalls in Russia’s transition:
Russia achieved a huge increase in inequality, at the same time that it managed to
shrink the economy, by up to a third according to some estimates. Living
standards collapsed with GDP levels, as life spans became shorter and health
worsened. All too late, it was recognized that without the right institutional
infrastructure, the profit motive--combined with full capital market liberalization--
could fail to provide incentives for wealth creation and could instead spark a drive17
to strip assets and ship wealth abroad.
!Imprudent Budget Deficit Management Burdening the State Budget and
Leading to Default. With the burden of rent-seeking subsidies on the state
budget and slow growth in taxable income, expenditures and debt service
continued to exceed state revenues. Taxable income was especially


EBRD, Transition 1998, op. cit, p. 17. Clifford Gatty and Barry Ickes, Foreign Affairs,16
Fall 1998. The Russian statistical agency, Goskomstat, calculates the official economy to be
as low as one-quarter of the official and unofficial economies combined.
Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Development Based on Participation, A Strategy for Transforming17
Societies,” Transition, newsletter of the World Bank and William Davidson Institute,
December 1998, p. 2.

constrained by exemptions and offsets for politically powerful, profitable
enterprises such as Gasprom, the world’s largest gas company. Revenue from
the sale of state assets in competitive auctions to foreign buyers failed to
materialize to generate substantial income due to high risk perception in the
global market. Flows from foreign direct investment fell far short of
expectations. Capital flight increased to over $20 billion a year and sizable
profits were transferred abroad. The state temporized by sequestration or
withholding of payments to workers, pensioners, military, and others not
politically powerful. Loans from international agencies, intended for reform
support, not budget balancing, brought much needed, but insufficient, financial
inflows. In this constrained budget context a new major source for financing
the budget deficit was found in the emerging markets for ruble-denominated
treasury bills (GKO’s) and bonds (OFZ's). The ruble had been stable and
appreciating in 1996 and Russian international credit ratings reached
investment-risk level in 1997-1998. Even though the GKO’s had to be sold at
high interest and short maturity, their sales became a major short-term means
of balancing the budget. As a result, by 1998 servicing the debt had risen to
about forty percent of the budget. With the August 17 collapse of the ruble18
and de facto default, the GKO market collapse put Russia in a solvency trap:
the Russian government could not sell more securities to service the debt it had
increased to manage its budget deficit. GKO’s thus emulated junk bonds of
the United States with a similar requirement for resolving the solvency trap,
including restructuring and recapitalizing its failing commercial banks with
many seeking the protection of bankruptcy.
Post-Crisis Scenarios and U.S. Policy Options
The policy options for the United States in relations with Russia would be
significantly different depending on the development of either the vicious cycle or
managed economy scenarios. The degree of effective engagement, the likelihood of
influence on Russian developments beneficial to U.S. interests and the implications
for future Russian developments would all be markedly different, depending on the
course of Russian economic development prior to the parliamentary election in
December, 1999 and the presidential election set for June, 2000. The election
outcomes would likely be influenced by the alternative scenarios and, in turn, affect
U.S. options in responding to the outcomes of parliamentary and presidential
elections.
In an environment of failed governance some suggest that the Russian reformers
might come back and reform might be renewed. This “worst is better” thinking is19


associated with the prospects of a Bulgarian or Argentine currency-board model in
EBRD, Transition 1998, p. 17. Keith Bush, Russian Economy in December 1998. Center18
for Strategic and International Studies (CSIS), Washington, DC.
Economists in the pre-crisis governments, such as Anatoly Chubais, reportedly favor the19
Bulgarian currency board. Anders Asland, Carnegie Foundation Report, September 1998.
George Soros’s Financial Times op. ed., August 15, 1998, prior to crisis favored a currency
(continued...)

which anti-reformers are discredited and true reformers make a political comeback
with an austerity program featuring a foreign-controlled currency board. The
Primakov government might be replaced before the December, 1999 parliamentary
elections, but introduction of the Bulgarian-Argentine model seems less likely than the
Belarus model in the successor government, because Belarus has an authoritarian,
reactionary government that controls the populace by use of intimidation and force.
Belarus might be the likely governance model of a vicious-cycle scenario. Under the
vicious cycle, the United States’ options for assisting Russia would be restricted; U.S.
presence and engagement would likely be sharply cut back. Humanitarian aid in food
and medicine may be even more needed and appropriate. Some cooperative security
programs may continue as still deemed in mutual security interest.20
If the United States is to continue to be engaged with Russia, it may be because
Primakov is able and willing to support reasonable efforts to manage its exit from
financial crisis through performance on the agreed Action Programs. The strength of
the Action Program and related negotiations for their coming to grips with the crisis
may lie in its service to the basic interests of both the current Russian government and
the donors and investors. Giving priority to an institutional restructuring strategy
promises improved prospects for economic growth, improved economic security and
closer ties with the global market. This strategy of the Action Program might
encourage profit-seeking over rent-seeking, thus pressuring the rent-seeking,
monopolistic oligarchs to shift the Russian economy toward a growth-promoting
strategy. The success of a strategy involving a cultural change in the Russian system21
is of interest to the United States and other donors. The predictability of the reform
scenario is contingent on a basic change in the incentive character of the Russian
system; a change in the way the elite is judged. Any benefit from reform is difficult
to project as many potential supporters of change would seem to be acting against
their interests.


(...continued)19
board. Hanson, op. cit; Steve H. Hanke and Kurt Schuler, “Keynes’s Russian Currency
Board,” in S.H. Hanke and A.A. Walters, eds., Capital Markets and Development, San
Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press, 1991; Steve H. Hanke and Kurt Schuler,
Currency Boards for Developing Countries, San Francisco: International Center for
Economic Growth, 1994.
Russia and the U.S. are cooperating on issues of nuclear weapons and security. From 199120
through September 1997, the United States obligated $857.2 million in Cooperative Threat
Reduction program (or "Nunn-Lugar") funds in order to help Russia dismantle nuclear
weapons and ensure the security of its nuclear weapons and weapons-grade nuclear material.
During the September 1998 summit, both countries agreed to share information when either
detects a ballistic missile launch anywhere in the world, and to reduce each country's stockpile
of weapons-grade plutonium by fifty metric tons. President Clinton's State of the Union
address (January 1999) included a proposal to increase U.S. funding for safeguarding nuclear
weapons in Russia and the NIS by 68% over five years, from $2.5 billion to $4.2 billion. The
Administration has proposed establishing a U.S.-Russian center to jointly monitor ballistic
early warning systems during December 1999-January 2000, to address concerns about Y2K
computer failures and strategic stability. (See CRS Report 98-299, Russian Missile
Technology and Nuclear Reactor Transfers to Iran, December 14, 1998.)
Anders Aslund, op. cit.21

There are specific and general aspects of the financial, security programs, and
humanitarian aid that merit particular attention and surveillance by the United States
under an economic management scenario:

1) Management of Debt Servicing. The precedent of restructuring the post-


World-War-II German and post-Communist Polish debt has been cited by
Russians and Poles. In each case the United States persuaded European22
sovereign and commercial debtors to accept substantial reductions in their claims
through Paris and London clubs negotiations. Innovative debt restructuring
approaches such as debt to equity and debt to nature may likewise again be
explored. Debt to equity would involve transfer of ownership of industrial
enterprises or mines to foreign creditors. Debt to nature would involve
conversion of debt by the Russian government funding environmental programs
in lieu of debt payment. Specific measures linking current debt settlements to
improved climate for foreign direct investment and provisions for gaining
transparency and repatriation of flight capital may also be in order.23
2) Bank Restructuring Process. Reconstructing the de facto bankrupt
commercial banks might be keyed to making them reliable intermediaries for
savings to investment in new capital stock. Primakov’s proposal for foreign
banks, including United States banks, to operate in Russia may be pursued if the
preconditions for effective operation of American banks in Russia are fulfilled.
Russian banking would be greatly improved by adding foreign-owned or joint
venture banks to the Russian banking system. Hungarian experience with
Citibank and other American banks could be instructive.
3) Budget Balancing. An improved budget for 1999 and adoption of critical
aspects of the draft tax code by the Duma are necessary but not alone sufficient
to proceed toward budget balancing. To effectively reduce redundant
expenditures, all rent-seeking activities need to be addressed including military,
administrative, as well as fiscal and monetary reforms. Without improved debt
management and radical bank restructuring, the debt service burden on the
budget might not be reduced sufficiently. Revenue from auctions of state assets
may also add to state revenue if proper restructuring of assets for sale and
necessary conditions for effective foreign management participation and transfer
of corporate management are addressed. American participation in bankruptcy
proceedings, especially akin to implementation of the Russian version of Chapter

11 of U.S. bankruptcy code, would be relevant.24


For U.S. role in Polish debt settlement see “The Congressional Role in United States22
Assistance Policy in Central-East European Economies in Transition,” William E. Schuerch,
East-Central European Economies in Transition, Joint Economic Committee, November

1994, pp. 343-344; cf. Patricia Wertman, Rescheduling Russia’s Debt: A Breakthrough?


CRS Report 96-506 E.
Removal of the Russian-Cypriot double taxation agreement allowing 5,000 Russian offshore23
companies operating in Cyprus to transfer profits and avoid Russian taxes would be a good
first step. Marrese, op. cit.
Roswell B. Perkins, “Managing Out of the Financial Crisis: The Potential of Business24
(continued...)

4) Foreign Direct Investment Generation. The legal and institutional
environment for attracting foreign direct investment is a critical factor in coping
with the financial crisis. FDI in turn may start its own virtuous cycle
encouraging export-driven growth. Key engines for the development may be in
the energy field: Russian participation in the Caspian Sea output and pipeline
development; Gasprom alliance with Ruhrgas and American investors in further
opening the European gas market to Russia. Opening oil fields with good25
profit prospects for U.S. energy companies with new production-sharing laws
might break the log jam in U.S. energy investment. Most-favored-nation trade
status was extended in 1992, and permanent waiver of the Jackson-Vanik.
General System of Preferences (GSP) status was granted in 1993. A double
taxation treaty entered into force in 1994, and a bilateral investment treaty in
1996, but tax and investment issues continue to vex bilateral commercial
relations in 1999. The Export-Import Bank has approved over $2 billion in
loans for U.S. capital equipment exports under an Oil and Gas Framework
Agreement. The Joint Commission for Economic and Technological
Cooperation (headed by the U.S. Vice President and the Russian Prime Minister)
is working to increase cooperation in science and technology, business
development, space, energy policy, environmental protection, health, defense
diversification and agriculture. The ninth meeting to have been chaired by Vice
President Gore and Prime Minister Primakov, initially scheduled for March 23-

25, 1999 in Washington, DC, is projected to be rescheduled.26


5) Nuclear and Conventional Weaponry Downscaling. The Nunn-Lugar
funding for encouraging dismantling of nuclear weapons and sale of enriched
uranium may enhance mutual security and benefit the Russian budget. (See CRS
Report 97-1027 F.) Related security issues such as arms sales and transfer of
military technology to China, India, and other states may be important to
reducing a Russian balance of payment deficit but are unsettling to peace and
stability in the U.S. view. Efforts of the Primakov government to bring these
activities more under central control may be helpful if the peace-disturbing
exports can be diminished or eliminated. The interrelationship of Russian security
policy toward Iran and the multinational development of the Caspian Sea energy
resources are issues of economic and security tangency that may continue to
spark disputes both bilaterally and between the United States government and
American business interests (see CRS Report 98-299, op. cit.).


(...continued)24
Workouts in Russia,” Russia Business Watch, Winter 1998-99, op. cit.
David M. Woodruff, “It’s Value That’s Virtual: Bartles, Rubles and the Place of Gazprom25
in the Russian Economy,” Working Paper 11, January 1999, Program on New Approaches
to Russian Security, Davis Center Harvard, Cambridge, MA.
See Commercial Issue Briefs, a private-sector guide to key issues affecting the business26
climate in Russia, prepared for the scheduled Gore-Primakov Commission meeting March 24-
25, 1999 by the American Chamber of Commerce in Russia and the U.S.-Russian Business
Council and presented to the U.S.-Russia Trade and Investment Forecast Conference held in
Washington, DC at that time.

6) Humanitarian Aid: Food. Regional food shortages have been exacerbated by
one of the poorest Russian harvests in years. U.S.-Russian governments agreed
on a large food aid program of 1.5 million metric tons of wheat and 100,000
metric tons of other food under a grant; an additional 1.5 million metric tons of
various grains were to be sold under a long-term, low-interest loan. The issue
of central government control, effectiveness and responsibility was raised in
American discussion by those concerned that the food would not go to the truly
needy and this concern may influence decisions in Congress to increase
assistance. Purported Russian food aid to Iraq and Serbia also cloud the aid
programs. Some Russians argued the food need is exaggerated and the large
U.S. agricultural surpluses had dictated the agreements (see CRS Issue Brief

92089, Russia, updated March 5, 1999).


Broader U.S.-led Conditionality
Negotiations and conditionality currently undertaken by the International
Monetary Fund appear to have been broadened to include concrete measures that may
be responded to by the World Bank, European Bank for Reconstruction and
Development (EBRD) and other bilateral and multilateral organizations in the G-7.
The debate led by Joseph Stiglitz and Nicholas Stern on the need to forge a new
transition strategy, a post-Washington consensus, focusing on building institutional
infrastructures and emphasizing enterprise efficiency has apparently resulted in a
broader U.S.-led reform assistance strategy and conditionality for Russia.
U.S. policy makers after August 1998 had seemed pessimistic in the short run
but continued to have long-run optimism for democratic market reform in Russia.
Deputy Secretary of State Talbott characterized the present crisis as a current Russian
time of troubles (using the Russian terms smutnye vremya) in recent speeches;
reference was also made to times of miracles (chudyesnye vremya) that may come in
the new millennium. However, by late Fall 1998, the U.S. and IMF policy began to27
stress continued U.S. commitment to an engagement policy with specific attention to
“concrete measures” prepared to respond to short-term results in the months ahead.28
The broader conditionality in current negotiations on the Russian program may be
appropriate not only because of the range of issues beyond the mission of specific
international financial institutions, but also for the broader implications for change in
Russia and in our bilateral relations. Moreover, the success of the reform policy
seems increasingly tied to the broader issue of how Russia defines its identity and
future. A change involving its incentive system and the institutional framework of
Russian governance may be deemed necessary and required. Secretary Talbott, by
framing the current financial crisis as a part of the identity crisis for Russia--a new
time of troubles--suggests that necessary economic reform may affect not only
Russian governance but Russian culture. For a favorable outcome Russia may need


Secretary Strobe Talbott, speech at Stanford University, September 17, 1998. John P.27
Hardt, Commentary on the IMF led Russian Assistance Program, Heritage Foundation, July

23, 1998 at a panel featuring Stanley Fischer and Alexei Mozhin of the IMF.


IMF-Russian communique, op. cit. Laurence Summers, op. cit.28

to address its broader cultural crisis in resolving its financial crisis in the short run--
then proceed, as other countries have, toward a democratic market system under a
rule of law. This aspect of change makes adopting necessary changes seem to be a
miracle, or as the Germans noted, a wirtshaftwunder. As Machiavelli earlier noted in
the Renaissance period, this kind of radical change may be most difficult but crucial.
And it ought to be remembered that there is nothing more difficult to take in hand, more
perilous to conduct, or more uncertain in its success, than to take the lead in the
introduction of a new order of things. Because the innovator has for enemies all those
who have done well under the old conditions, and lukewarm defenders in those who may
do well under the new. This coolness arises partly from fear of the opponents, who have
the laws on their side, and partly from the incredulity of men, who do not readily believe
in new things until they have had a long experience of them.
Thus it happens that whenever those who are hostile have the opportunity to attack they29
do it like partisans, whilst the others defend lukewarmly. . . .
This broader political-cultural rationale for incrementally dealing with Russia’s
current crisis has been gaining more adherents among professional Russia watchers.
While noting that the current government has survived the immediate crisis better in
the short term than expected, some still view an incremental approach as too little, too
late to hold sway with Russian voters later this year. At the same time, others argue30
that furtherance at this time of the managed-economy reform plan, acceptable to
foreign donors and investors, is necessary over a sustained period to decrease
economic inefficiencies, revive economic growth, and enhance internal and
international political support. What does appear clear is that Russia cannot continue
to “muddle through” or just survive its economic crisis. Should he follow this path,
Primakov risks losing both internal as well as international support. Primakov’s
dilemma may thus be that neither action nor inaction are riskless while continuing to
push forward on his Action Plan.


Niccolo Machiavelli, The Prince, 1513.29
Michael Marrese, “Russia: Survival, Not Revival,” International Fixed Income Research,30
Chase Securities Inc., London: April 16, 1999.