MAJOR TAX ISSUES IN THE 106TH CONGRESS: A RETROSPECTIVE SUMMARY

CRS Report for Congress
th
Major Tax Issues in the 106 Congress:
A Retrospective Summary
February 13, 2001
Edited by David L. Brumbaugh
Specialist in Public Finance
Government and Finance Division


Congressional Research Service The Library of Congress

Major Tax Issues in the 106 Congress:
A Retrospective Summary
Summary
Taxes were a major focus of congressional attention during the 106th Congress.
In 1999 Congress passed a set of tax cuts with the Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act
(H.R. 2488; TRRA). However, President Clinton vetoed the bill, arguing that the
cuts were too large (an estimated $792 billion over 10 years). Early in 2000, Congress
signaled its intention of revisiting tax cuts with passage of a fiscal year (FY) 2001
budget resolution (H.Con.Res. 290) calling for a five-year tax cut of $175 billion.
However, Republican leaders stated their intention to consider tax legislation in a
series of more narrow bills rather than with one omnibus tax-cut bill as in 1999.
By October, 2000, Congress addressed many of the same tax cuts that were in
the vetoed 1999 bill, but in a series of separate bills. The House passed:
!H.R. 4810, a tax cut for married couples;
!H.R. 3081, a tax cut linked to an increase in the minimum wage;
!H.R. 4516, an appropriations bill that also would repeal the federal tax on
telecommunications;
!H.R. 8, phasing out the estate and gift tax;
!H.R. 1102, a pension bill including individual retirement account (IRA)
provisions;
!H.R. 4865, repealing taxes on Social Security benefits;
!H.R. 4923, providing tax benefits for economically distressed communities.
On the Senate side, tax cuts linked to a minimum wage increase were passed as
part of H.R. 833, a broad bankruptcy bill. The Senate also approved S. 1134,
containing a number of tax benefits for education and bills phasing out the estate tax,
providing a tax cut for married couples, and repealing the telephone excise tax.
In August, the President vetoed the marriage-penalty bill (H.R. 4810) and the
estate tax bill (H.R. 8), generally arguing that the bills were not fiscally responsible
and were not fair. In its own FY 2001 budget plan, the Administration proposed
more modest tax cuts, amounting to a net tax reduction of $168 billion over 10 years.
No action was taken in Congress on most of the Administration’s proposals.
On October 26, the House passed the Taxpayer Relief Act of 2000 as part of
H.R. 2614, a non-tax small-business bill. The bill proposed to cut taxes by an
estimated $240.4 billion over 10 years, and contained provisions already passed by the
House or Senate during the course of the year: small business tax measures and a
minimum wage increase; community renewal measures; health care tax provisions;
and liberalized IRA rules and pension tax changes. President Clinton threatened to
veto the bill, and the Senate did not consider the bill. Instead, Congress passed (and
the President signed) two narrower bills: H.R. 4577, an appropriations bill that
included community renewal measures, and H.R. 4986, which replaced the Foreign
Sales Corporation (FSC) export tax benefit with a new benefit designed to comply
with international trade agreements.



Contents
The General Tax Policy Debate.....................................1
Taxes in 1999..............................................1
The Debate in 2000..........................................1
The Economic Context...........................................3
Federal Tax Burden..........................................3
Economic Performance.......................................3
Major Tax Proposals.............................................4
The Taxpayer Relief Act of 2000 (Part of H.R. 2614)................4
The Death Tax Elimination Act (H.R. 8)..........................6
Tax Cuts for Married Couples (H.R. 4810)........................6
Tax Benefits for Education (H.R. 7 and S. 1134)....................7
Taxes and Minimum Wage Legislation (H.R. 3081; S. 625 and H.R. 833).7
Proposals in the President’s FY2001 Budget.......................9
The Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act of 1999 (H.R. 2488).............9
A Closer Look at Selected Issues...................................11
Marriage Tax Penalties and Bonuses............................11
The Estate Tax............................................11
The Alternative Minimum Tax for Individuals.....................12
Capital Gains..............................................14
Tax Treatment of Savings....................................15
Tobacco Taxes............................................16
Fundamental Tax Reform Proposals (Including Flat Tax Plans)........16



Major Tax Issues in 2000:
A Retrospective Summary
The General Tax Policy Debate
Taxes in 1999
Much of the tax policy debate in 1999 centered on surpluses in the federal
budget and on whether or not to use at least part of the surpluses to finance tax cuts.
In 1999, the budget situation was this: there was an overall surplus in the federal
budget for FY1999, but the surplus consisted exclusively of surpluses in the off-
budget accounts – primarily that in the Social Security accounts. The on-budget
accounts remained in deficit in FY1999 but were projected to move into surplus in
FY2000. With its FY2000 budget proposal in February, 1999, the Clinton
Administration proposed to save the surpluses in the Social Security accounts by
using them to pay down the federal debt. At the same time, the President proposed
to use the projected on-budget surpluses to finance a modest tax cut – $327 billion
over 10 years – and to provide added funding for Medicare, defense spending, and a
number of other programs.
Congressional Republicans likewise proposed to use the off-budget surpluses to
pay down the federal debt, but proposed using most of the projected on-budget
surpluses to finance a larger tax cut. The congressional budget resolution for FY2000
called for a tax cut of $792 billion over 10 years. In August, Congress passed the
Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act of 1999 (TRRA; H.R. 2488), which contained the
tax cut proposed in the budget resolution. President Clinton vetoed the bill, stating
that the tax cut was too large and would have undesirable distributional effects.
The Debate in 2000
The general terms of the debate over tax policy remained much the same in 2000
as in 1999: how much of the surplus should be used for federal debt reduction, for
spending programs, and for tax cuts? The budget resolution passed by Congress on
April 13 (H.Con.Res. 290) called for a five-year tax cut of $175 billion. The
President’s FY2001 budget plan (which has not been adopted) called for a smaller tax
cut of $168 billion over 10 years.
While the terms of the 2000 debate carried over from 1999, the legislative
approach in Congress was different. Congress revisited many of the tax cuts
contained in the TRRA, but with a more incremental approach, passing various parts
of the tax cut as stand-alone bills. The most prominent of the congressional tax cut
bills were a phase-out of the estate and gift tax (H.R. 8, passed by the House on June

9 and the Senate on July 14) and a tax cut for married couples (H.R. 4810; passed by



the House on July 20 and by the Senate on July 21). Other prominent tax cut bills
included:
!a tax cut for small businesses linked to a minimum wage increase (H.R. 3810
in the House, passed on March 9; H.R. 833 in the Senate, passed on February

1), containing tax cuts for small business linked to a minimum wage;


!a pension reform bill that included provisions that would increase over three
years annual contribution limits on Individual Retirement Accounts from
current law’s $2,000 to $5,000 (H.R. 1102, passed by the House on July 19;
later passed again by the House as part of H.R. 5173); and
!a measure repealing of the 3% federal telecommunications excise tax
(included in H.R. 4516, an appropriations bill that was passed by the House on
September 14 and the by the Senate on October 12).
The President vetoed the telephone excise tax repeal, as well as both the estate
tax bill and the tax cut for married couples. In the case of the latter two bills, he
argued that an insufficient share of their benefits would accrue to middle- and lower-
income persons. The President also argued that the tax cut for couples was poorly
targeted.
The legislative year drew to a close with Congress considering H.R. 2614, a bill
that repackaged a number of measures that had been passed by the House or Senate
over the course of the year, including tax cuts linked with small businesses and a
minimum wage increase, numerous pension measures, and tax benefits for
economically distressed communities.
President Clinton stated that he would veto H.R. 2614, and the Senate did not
consider the measure. The 106th Congress came to a close with Congress passing
(and the President signing) two more narrow tax measures. H.R. 4577, an
appropriations bill, included a number of tax benefits designed to assist economically
distressed communities. H.R. 4986 contained provision replacing the Foreign Sales
Corporation (FSC) export tax benefit with a new benefit similar in magnitude to FSC.
In response to a complaint by the European Union, a World Trade Organization
(WTO) panel in 1999 ruled that FSC violated the agreements on which the WTO is
based, and that prohibit export subsidies. H.R. 4986's new benefit is designed to be
WTO-compliant, although the EU remains skeptical, and has asked the WTO to rule
on the new provisions.
We next step back from the legislative details and look at the economic context
in which tax policy was debated.



The Economic Context
Federal Tax Burden1
In 2000, many supporters of a tax cut pointed to the relatively high aggregate
level of taxes compared to the economy. As a percent of gross domestic product
(GDP), federal taxes were at their highest level since the end of World War II: 20.0%,
in fiscal year 1999 and 20.6% in 2000. This was not, however, a dramatic departure
from past levels; since the mid 1950s, federal taxes as a percentage of GDP have
remained within a range of between 17% and just below 20% of GDP. Growth in the
economy combined with federal legislation to reduce the budget deficit (tax increases
in 1990 and 1993) produced a slight increase in federal revenues as a percentage of
GDP over the last several years. In FY1990, federal taxes accounted for only 18.0%
of GDP.
While there were some fluctuations in the distribution of the federal tax burden
over the last 20 years, the fluctuations were concentrated at the ends of the income
spectrum. During the 1980s the federal tax burden increased for lower-income
families and decreased for upper income families. This trend was reversed in the
1990s with tax reductions at the lower end of the income spectrum and tax increases
at the upper end of the income spectrum. Families in the middle income brackets,
however, experienced very little change in their federal tax burdens over this period,
despite legislated tax cuts. Some of the benefits of the tax changes contained in the
1997 Act did not necessarily accrue to middle-income families. The $500 child tax
credit has likely reduced federal taxes for middle income families, but only those
families with qualifying children. The benefits of reductions in the tax on capital
gains, expanded IRAs, and other savings and investment incentives have probably
tended to accrue to families at the upper end of the income spectrum.
Economic Performance
Many of the tax proposals considered in 2000 were intended to boost long-term
growth by increasing private saving and investment, thereby expanding the nation’s
capital stock. The impact of these various proposals on saving is perhaps the most
prominent economic performance issue the proposals present. First, can tax
incentives for saving or tax benefits for investment actually boost the nation’s rate of
private saving and investment? Second, total national saving consists of private
saving minus government borrowing. Thus, is any expansion the proposals may cause
in private saving larger than any increase they also cause in the federal budget deficit
(or decrease in the federal budget surplus)? If provisions actually cause an increase
in total national saving, the nation’s capital stock expands, resulting in higher
economic growth. Yet economic analysis is not clear on whether and by how much
private savings responds to tax incentives.


1Authored by Gregg A. Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance
Division.

A number of the tax provisions that were considered provided favorable tax
treatment to particular types of economic activity, extending special tax credits,
deductions, or exclusions to certain activities. Economic theory suggests that
favorable treatment for specified activities can distort the economy’s ordinary
decision making and channel more resources into the favored activity than would
otherwise occur. Since the economy’s resources are limited, this also means that
resources are simultaneously drawn away from activities that are not tax-favored.
The question that economic analysis pursues is whether a specific intervention in
resource allocation actually improves overall economic performance.
An important aspect of any tax proposal is its effect on federal revenues and the
federal budget deficit or surplus. Deficit reduction has been a primary focus of budget
debates over the past several years. The effects on federal revenue of several
elements of the various tax proposals have been questioned. For instance, as noted
earlier, economic analysis does not provide clear-cut answers about the extent to
which economic activity might increase in response to tax incentives. As a result, the
ultimate revenue effects of broad-based tax cuts or tax incentives for saving are
unclear. In addition, several changes — notably, those involving IRAs, depreciation,
and capital gains — would likely register a much larger revenue impact a number of
years in the future rather than in the near term. Thus, revenue estimates confined to
these proposals’ first few years do not show the potential long-run magnitude of their
revenue loss. Their supporters, however, generally argue that the measures would
stimulate economic growth that would shrink any revenue loss.
We next take a closer look at the most prominent of the specific tax proposals.
Major Tax Proposals
The Taxpayer Relief Act of 2000 (Part of H.R. 2614)
The last major piece of tax legislation considered by the 106th Congress was the
Taxpayer Relief Act of 2000, which was incorporated into H.R. 2614, a non-tax small
business bill. According to the Joint Committee on Taxation, the tax provisions
would have reduced revenue by an estimated $73.9 billion over five years and $240
billion over 10 years. Its principal elements were in many cases provisions previously
passed by the House and/or Senate as parts of other bills, and fell into five groups: a
proposal to replace current law’s Foreign Sales Corporation (FSC) tax benefit for
exporting; tax benefits for small business that were linked to legislation raising the
minimum wage; tax cuts related to health care; pension tax provisions; and school
construction provisions.
H.R. 2614 was passed by the House on October 26. However, President Clinton
threatened to veto the bill, stating that it was not a bipartisan product and ignored
certain Democratic concerns.2 The Senate never voted on the measure.


2BNA Daily Tax Report, October 27, 2000, p. GG-1.

The bill included an increase in the minimum wage, and with it a set of tax
benefits for small business similar to those in previous House and Senate minimum
wage bills. H.R. 2614 included: an increase in the business meals tax deduction to
70% from current law’s 50%; an increase in the “expensing” tax benefit for
investment to $35,000 from current law’s $20,000; and an extension of the work
opportunity tax credit through June, 2004.
The health care provisions related primarily to insurance. They included an
“above-the-line” deduction (a deduction that can be claimed by non-itemizers) for
health insurance in cases where individuals pay at least 50% of their insurance costs;
an above-the-line deduction for long-term care insurance. The bill also moved up
from 2003 to 2001 the effective date on which self-employed persons can deduct
100% of their health insurance. The bill also extended the deduction to persons
choosing not to participate in an employer-subsidized plan.
The bill contained numerous tax-related retirement and pension provisions. The
most prominent, however, were those related to individual retirement accounts
(IRAs). The bill provided a phased-in increase of the annual contribution limit from
current law’s $2,000 to $5,000. The limit would be indexed.
H.R. 2614's school construction provisions generally relax certain rules that
apply to tax-exempt school-construction bonds issued by state and local governments.
Among the bill’s provisions are liberalized “arbitrage” provisions that lengthen to
four years from two years the period of time within which governments must spend
bond proceeds. The bill also creates a new kind class of qualified zone academy bond
that, like other zone academy bonds, provides a federal tax credit to purchasers rather
than interest payments.
The community revitalization provisions contain a number of tax benefits
designed to assist economically distressed communities. Along with a number of
other provisions, the bill would designate 40 new “renewal communities” and nine
new “empowerment zones” within which employers would receive wage credits and
businesses would receive an additional investment expensing allowance. The bill
would also increase current law’s low income housing tax credit.
H.R. 2614 also contained a provision that replaced current law’s Foreign Sales
Corporation (FSC) with a new export tax benefit. The countries of the European
Union (EU) had charged that the FSC provisions constituted an export subsidy and
therefore contravened the World Trade Organization (WTO) agreements. A WTO
panel subsequently issued a report that supported the EU’s charge, and under WTO
procedures, the United States was required to bring its tax provisions into compliance
by October 1, 2000; the EU agreed to extend the deadline to November 1.
The Administration supported the FSC-replacement provisions in H.R. 2614,
but, as noted above, threatened to veto the bill for other reasons. Accordingly, the
Senate passed H.R. 4986, a stand-alone set of FSC provisions. The House passed the
same version of H.R. 4986 on November 14, following the elections. The President
signed the measure into law on November 15 (Public Law 106-519).



The Death Tax Elimination Act (H.R. 8)
H.R. 8 proposed to phase down, then completely repeal the federal estate and
gift tax. The phase-down would have gradually reduced the tax rates currently
applicable to estates over the period 2001-09. Full repeal was to be effective in 2010.
In 2010 the bill also would have repealed current law’s “step up in basis”
available for inherited assets that have appreciated in value over a decedent’s lifetime.
Under current law, when a person inherits an asset and subsequently sells it, the
“basis” of the asset – the amount that can be deducted from the sales price in
calculating capital gains under the income tax – is its value at the time of death. With
two exceptions, H.R. 8 replaced this step up in basis with a “carryover basis.” That
is, when an inherited asset is sold, its basis in the hands of the beneficiary is the basis
it had in the hands of the decedent. The step up in basis was retained for a decedent’s
property up to $1.3 million and to property transferred to a spouse up to $3 million.
H.R. 8 was approved by the House on June 9 and by the Senate on July 14. The
President vetoed the measure on August 31, arguing that it was fiscally irresponsible
and not fair. The Joint Committee on Taxation estimated the five-year revenue cost
of the bill at $28 billion.
Tax Cuts for Married Couples (H.R. 4810)
The Marriage Tax Penalty Relief Act (H.R. 6) was initially approved by the full
House on February 10. The same bill was again passed by the House on July 12 as
H.R. 4810.
The House bill took the same approach to taxes paid by married couples as did
the TRRA in 1999. The proposal made four changes: a standard deduction for
married couples expanded to twice that of singles; increases in the beginning and end-
points of the earned income tax credit’s phaseout range; and a phased-in doubling for
married couples of the width of the lowest (15%) tax bracket. The bill also repealed
restrictions on refundable personal tax credits under the alternative minimum tax.
According to Joint Tax Committee estimates, the proposal would result in a revenue
loss of $182.3 billion over 10 years. (By comparison, the total net revenue loss
estimated for the TRRA was $792 billion over 10 years; President Clinton’s proposal
for married couples would reduce revenues by an estimated $45 billion.)
On March 30, the Senate Finance Committee approved a bill reducing the
marriage penalty that was estimated to reduce revenues by $247.8 billion over 10
years. The bill contained the same basic provisions as H.R. 4810, but with two
additions. The bill doubled the width of the 28% tax bracket for couples, not just the
15% bracket. The bill also made permanent the full creditability of nonrefundable
credits against the alternative minimum tax (AMT) and provided that refundable
credits would not be reduced by the AMT. The bill was approved by the full Senate
on July 17 as an amended version of H.R. 4810.
A conference committee version of the bill was approved by the House on July

20 and the Senate on July 21. As with both the House and Senate bills, the



conference bill doubled the standard deduction for couples; as in the House bill, it
increased the beginning and end points of the Earned Income Tax Credit’s phase-out
by $2,000. As with the House bill, the conference measure doubled the width of the
15% rate bracket for couples, but not that of the 28% bracket. The widening was
phased in over the period 2000-04. The bill also permitted nonrefundable credits to
offset the AMT, and, beginning in 2002, provided that the refundable child credit and
earned income tax credit were not to be reduced by the AMT.
On August 5 the President vetoed H.R. 4810, arguing that its revenue cost was
excessive and that too large a share of the tax cut would accrue to couples currently
receiving a marriage tax bonus rather than a marriage tax penalty.3
Tax Benefits for Education (H.R. 7 and S. 1134)
On March 2, the Senate approved S. 1134, a bill containing a number of tax
benefits for education. On March 22, the House Committee on Ways and Means also
approved an education bill (H.R. 7), but the full House did not act on the measure
before the end of the year.
Prominent provisions of both bills were an expansion of education savings
account contribution limits to $2,000 from current law’s $500, along with extension
of qualified withdrawals to include primary and secondary school expenses in addition
to current law’s college costs. Both bills also expanded current law’s qualified tax-
favored tuition programs to include private as well as State institutions and excluded
distributions from gross income. Both the Ways and Means and Senate bills repealed
the 60-month limit on student interest deductions; the Ways and Means bill increased
the related income thresholds for the provision’s phase-out. Both bills provided a
new four year expenditure schedule for school construction bonds under the tax
code’s arbitrage rebate rules. (This bond provision was subsequently included in H.R.

2614, passed by the House on October 26.)


The major difference between the two bills was the presence in the Senate bill
of a permanent exclusion from gross income for employer-provided undergraduate
and graduate education assistance.
According to Joint Tax Committee estimates, the Senate bill would reduce
revenues by $7.7 billion over five years and $21.3 billion over 10 years; the Ways and
Means bill would reduce revenue by an estimated $3.8 billion over five years and
$11.6 billion over 10 years.
Taxes and Minimum Wage Legislation (H.R. 3081; S. 625 and
H.R. 833)
The full Senate and the House Ways and Means Committee each passed bills on
November 9, 1999, that would increase the minimum hourly wage by $1 over three
years. Both bills also contained tax provisions designed to reduce business taxes along


3BNA Daily Tax Report, August 8, 2000, p. G-2.

with the increase in the minimum wage. On February 1, 2000, the Senate folded the
minimum wage and associated tax provisions of S. 625 into a broad bill relating to
bankruptcy, H.R. 833. The Senate subsequently approved the measure.
On March 9, the full House passed a tax cut bill linked with other legislation
increasing the minimum wage. The bill was patterned after tax cuts approved in
November 1999 by the Ways and Means Committee and that were contained in an
earlier version of the minimum wage bill. The tax cuts were initially passed as part
of H.R. 3832, but were then combined with House-passed minimum wage legislation
as part of H.R. 3081. According to Joint Tax Committee estimates, the tax cuts
would reduce revenues by $45.7 billion over five years; it contains no revenue raising
offsets. Prominent provisions of the bill include:
!a reduction in estate and gift tax rates (the largest tax cut in the bill; see also,
however, H.R. 8, which would gradually repeal the estate tax);an increase in
the expensing tax benefit for small business investment to $30,000, permitting
the immediate deduction of amounts that would otherwise be depreciated over
a number of years;
!rescission of the repeal of the installment method of accounting that was
enacted in 1999 as part of the “extenders” bill (H.R. 1180); acceleration of the
scheduled phase-in of a 100% deduction for the health insurance costs of self-
employed individuals;
!an increase in the portion of business meals that can be deducted; to 60% from
current law’s 50%; an increase in contribution limits for qualified pension
plans, with other pension changes; and
!tax benefits directed at economically distressed areas.
The provisions were similar to measures included in the “small business” and
“pension” portions of the vetoed Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act of 1999 (H.R.

2488).


The Senate-passed tax provisions associated with its minimum wage bill were
quite similar to those of the Ways and Means bill, but with a few differences. The
Senate bill contained the same acceleration of the full deductibility of health insurance
for the self employed. However, it also provided for a phased-in, above-the-line
deduction for health and long-term-care insurance for individuals not covered by
employment related plans. The Senate bill also increased the investment expensing
allowance to $30,000 compared to $25,000 under the Ways and Means Committee
bill and allowed 80% of business meals and entertainment expenses of small
businesses to be deductible. It made the Work Opportunity Tax Credit permanent.
The Senate measure did not contain the estate tax provisions contained in H.R. 3081.
When it was initially passed, the Senate bill contained several items that would
increase revenues. These items – an increase related to installment sales and one for
real estate investment trusts (REITs) – were later enacted with H.R. 1180. According
to recent estimates by the Joint Committee on Taxation, the Senate-passed tax
provisions of H.R. 833 would reduce revenue by $25.7 billion over five years.



According to news reports, procedural issues delayed consideration of the bill
by a conference committee.4 The issues are related to the Constitution’s requirement
that tax bills originate in the House rather than the Senate; the House version of the
bankruptcy bill contains no tax provisions.
The Administration stated its opposition to the manner in which the
congressional bills would implement their $1 increase in the minimum wage; the $1
increase would occur over three years, in three annual installments. The
Administration favored implementing the $1 over two years. In addition, the
Administration and some congressional Democrats have voiced opposition to the
minimum wage bill’s tax cuts, arguing they are risky and favor upper-income
individuals. On October 26, the House passed the Taxpayer Relief Act of 2000 as
part of H.R. 2614, a non-tax small business bill. The bill included (in slightly modified
form) the minimum wage-related tax provisions initially passed as part of H.R. 3081.
Proposals in the President’s FY2001 Budget
On February 7, 2000, the Clinton Administration published details of the tax and
other budget proposals the President had previously outlined in his State of the Union
message. In broad terms, the President proposed gross tax cuts totaling $350 billion
over 10 years (according to Administration estimates), partly offset by revenue-raising
measures of $182 billion; the proposed net tax cut was thus an estimated $168 billion
over 10 years. In substance, the tax proposals were selective, for the most part
applying to a variety of narrow areas rather than across-the-board. In general, the tax
cuts were aimed at particular goals and activities favored by the Administration.
Prominent areas proposed for tax relief included: married couples, retirement saving,
child care, education, long-term care, and persons covered by the minimum tax. The
largest revenue-raising measure was an increase in tobacco taxes. Other revenue-
raising items were small, narrow, and varied, and included a variety of measures
aimed at what the Administration identified as “unwarranted” tax benefits and
corporate tax shelters. Congress did not take action on the majority of the President’s
proposals during 2000.
The Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act of 1999 (H.R. 2488)
The FY2000 budget resolution Congress passed in April 1999 called for a tax
cut of $792 billion over 10 years. On July 22 the House approved a plan (H.R. 2488)
to cut taxes by the $792 billion specified in the budget; the full Senate approved a tax
cut bill on July 30. Like the House bill, the Senate plan proposed to cut taxes by $792
billion, but differed in its details. On August 4, a conference committee version of the
bill was completed, and both the House and the Senate approved the measure on
August 5. However, President Clinton vetoed the bill on September 23.
Like the House and Senate bills before it, the conference version of H.R. 2488
contained a tax cut estimated at $792 billion over its first 10 years. A prominent
feature of the conference bill was that a number of its largest provisions – for
example, the rate reductions and marriage penalty relief – expire (“sunset”) after


4 BNA Daily Tax Report, July 13, 2000, p. G-7

2008. Also, in a provision taken from the House bill, the conference bill’s rate
reductions were contingent on federal debt reduction.
The centerpiece of H.R. 2488's tax cuts was an across-the-board reduction in
individual tax rates. It provided for each individual income tax rate to be reduced by
one percentage point on a phased-in basis. Thus, for example, the 15% rate was
reduced to 14% in 2003 and thereafter; the remaining rates were scheduled to be
reduced in 2005 and thereafter.
Other prominent provisions of H.R. 2488 included:
!Addressing the marriage tax penalty by making the standard deduction for
couples twice that of singles and by increasing the new 14% bracket for
couples to twice that of the singles’ bracket. The bill also addressed the effect
of marriage on the earned income credit by increasing the income range over
which the credit is phased out for joint returns.
!An increase in the rate of the dependent care tax credit.
!A phased-in above-the-line deduction for health insurance expenditures and
long-term care insurance.
!Expansion of tax-favored education savings accounts, including an increase in
the contribution limit and their extension to primary and secondary education
expenses.
!Reductions in capital gains tax rates: the bill cut the current 20% and 10%
rates to 18% and 8%, respectively. Assets were to be indexed for inflation
occurring after 1999.
!Along with other IRA expansions, an increase in allowable annual IRA
contribution limits to $5,000 from current law’s $2,000.
!Gradual repeal of the individual alternative minimum tax.
!Reduction of the corporate alternative minimum tax by repeal of the 90% limit
on foreign tax credits and net operating losses.
!Gradual repeal of the estate and gift tax.
!Permitting U.S.-based multinationals to use so-called “worldwide allocation”
of interest expense in calculating their foreign tax credits.
!Extending a number of expiring tax benefits for varying periods of time.
In addition to its tax cuts, the bill contained a small number of revenue-raising
provisions. The revenue raisers were generally narrow in scope and small in size.
While they were scattered throughout the tax code, they generally would have applied
to business and investment income.



A Closer Look at Selected Issues
Marriage Tax Penalties and Bonuses5
Defining the married couple as a single tax unit, as does the current federal
individual income tax, conflicts with the principle of marriage neutrality. Marriage
neutrality means that the tax system should not influence the choice of individuals
with regard to their marital status. However, under the current federal income tax
system, some married couples pay more income tax than they would as two unmarried
singles (a marriage tax penalty) while other married couples pay less income tax than
they would as two unmarried singles (a marriage tax bonus). A marriage-neutral
income tax is an elusive goal. Marriage neutrality conflicts with two other concepts
of equity: progressivity and equal taxation of couples with equal incomes.
Regardless of how these three concepts of equity are juggled, an income tax can
achieve any two of these goals but cannot simultaneously achieve all three.
As described above (see the section entitled “Tax Cuts for Married Couples”),
legislation that would reduce taxes for married couples has had a prominent place in

2000's tax policy debate.


The Estate Tax6
The estate tax was enacted in 1916 as a revenue source for World War I. As
with wealth taxes before it, and like most other taxes, revenue was the primary
rationale for the tax. Why the estate tax rather than other possible sources of
revenue? There were essentially two reasons: first, the estate tax was viewed as a
type of fee for the services by the government in protecting property during lifetime,
as well as a fee to cover part of the cost of probating the estate at death. Also, the
estate tax was chosen over other taxes for reasons of equity and to reduce the
concentration of wealth. In 1997, when the exemption was $600,000, only 3.9% of
decedents (90,006 of 2.3 million decedents) left estates large enough to file a tax
return. Further, less than half of those required to file a return (42,901, or 1.9% of
all estates) owed tax.
The federal estate tax is a tax on wealth and as such, it raises some of the same
economic issues as annual wealth taxes, which are economically equivalent to annual
capital income taxes. Economic theory views the accumulation of wealth to be largely
the result of an individual’s decision to postpone consumption, to save and
accumulate capital during one’s life of work and investment, and to take risks. As
such the estate tax is a tax on accumulated savings imposed at the end of one’s life.
And the tax is paid out of the economy’s total supply of private savings — reducing
private sector savings and increasing government savings (i.e, tax revenue). But an
important economic question is what is the effect, if any, on the lifetime savings


5Authored by Gregg Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance
Division.
6Authored by Sal Lazzari, Specialist in Public Finance, Resources, Science, and Industry
Division.

behavior of individuals? Does the estate tax reduce savings rates? Does the tax
reduce the incentives to accumulate capital? Or do individuals compensate for the tax
by increasing their accumulation of pre-tax wealth such that enough after-tax wealth
is accumulated to bequeath to their heirs? Such might be the case if individuals derive
utility either from the wealth itself, or from their heirs’ (children) welfare, or both.
There is no clear answer to these questions.
The estate tax is part of the overall cost of bequeathing wealth to one’s heirs.
The existence of the estate tax is believed to reduce the level of planned bequests. If
so, reducing the estate tax is likely to increase planned bequests, but according to
economic theory, the effect on savings is uncertain. The estate tax does create
incentives for lifetime gift giving, for estate planning, for substantial charitable
donations, and for the establishment of trusts. With federal marginal estate tax rates
ranging as high as 55%, significant resources and time may be expended at minimizing
the estate tax burden. And a relatively large estate planning industry — accountants,
lawyers, and financial advisors — is available to wealth holders to minimize any
potential estate tax burden.
One economic effect — the effect on farms and small businesses — has
dominated the recent debate over the estate tax and played a key role in the estate tax
cuts enacted as part of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. The estate tax is imposed
on business capital and wealth — land, equipment, stock, buildings, etc. — in addition
to personal wealth. It is argued that this takes capital out of farms and small
businesses, inhibiting their transfer to heirs and retention in the family; that the tax can
cause the break-up or dissolution of family farms and small business. A sale of the
assets to or merger of the enterprise with a large competitor could reduce market
competition and inhibit economic efficiency. These effects were a principal reason for
the 1981 estate tax reductions, and have been a key impetus for most of the recent
proposals to reduce the estate tax. However, the estate tax is only one of many
possible causes for the sale of farm or business assets outside the family at death, and
not always the principal cause. Further, recent data suggest that few farms or small
businesses are likely to encounter an estate tax liability.
For information on legislation relating to the estate tax, see the section above
entitled “The Death Tax Elimination Act (H.R. 8).”
The Alternative Minimum Tax for Individuals7
To make sure that every person with significant income pays at least a minimum
of taxes while still preserving the economic and social incentives in the tax code,
Congress created, in 1969, what is now known as the individual alternative minimum
tax (AMT). In essence, the AMT is a tax on the use of tax incentives and preferences
and was primarily targeted at upper-income taxpayers who were thought to overuse
these preferences to reduce or eliminate their regular income tax liabilities. However,
since its inception, the value and effectiveness of the minimum tax has routinely been
the subject of congressional debate. Recently, many analysts have voiced concern


7Authored by Gregg Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance
Division.

over the expected increase in the number of upper-middle income taxpayers who may
be subject to AMT coverage in the near future. This increase will occur because of
the combined effects of inflation and recent legislative changes to the regular income
tax.
The structural components of the regular income tax are indexed for inflation
while the structural components of the AMT are not. Consequently, the gap between
tax liabilities under the regular income tax and the AMT will shrink over time and
many taxpayers could end up subject to the unindexed AMT or experience reductions
in their nonrefundable tax credits under the regular income tax solely as the result of
inflation. The potential problems of an indexed regular tax and an unindexed AMT
have long been recognized by tax analysts. The Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT)
released estimates showing that in 1997, approximately 605,000 taxpayers were
subject to the AMT but that the number of taxpayers subject to the AMT will increase
to around 9.2 million by tax year 2007. These estimates, however, were made prior
to the passage of the Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997. When the effects of both inflation
and the 1997 legislative changes are taken into account, preliminary estimates indicate
that by 2007, the number of taxpayers falling under either the AMT or AMT limits on
their tax credits under the regular income tax will grow to almost 12 million. In
general, nonrefundable personal tax credits under the regular income tax are limited
to the amount by which a taxpayer’s regular income tax liability exceeds his tentative
minimum tax. Hence, even if a taxpayer owes no AMT, the AMT could reduce the
value of his nonrefundable personal tax credits under the regular income tax.
The child tax credit and the HOPE tax credit are the two changes contained in
the 1997 act that would have the largest impact in increasing the number of taxpayers
subject to the AMT, either directly or indirectly. Many taxpayers in the upper-middle
income ranges likely will see the value of these two credits reduced or eliminated
because of the AMT. The prospect that the AMT is now going to affect many upper-
middle income taxpayers who were not subject to the tax in the past has prompted
some calls in Congress for action to remedy the situation. Congress did take limited
action in 1998 by including a provision in the Omnibus Consolidated and Emergency
Supplemental Appropriations Act (PL. 105-277) that will mitigate part of the
problems with the AMT for tax year 1998. Under this provision, nonrefundable
personal tax credits are fully allowed against a taxpayer’s regular income tax liability
for 1998 even if the credits are in excess of the amount by which the taxpayer’s
regular income tax exceeds the amount of his tentative minimum tax.
In November, 1999, Congress passed (and the President signed) H.R. 1180,
which included a temporary extension of the existing provision that permits
individuals to offset their regular income tax by the full amount of their nonrefundable
tax credits, regardless of the amount of their AMT. The provision was extended
through 2001. And in 2000, Congress included a provision to make full creditability
of the nonrefundable permanent in H.R. 4810, the bill providing a tax cut for married
couples. As noted above, however, the President vetoed the bill.



Capital Gains8
Since the enactment of the individual income tax in 1913, the appropriate
taxation of capital gains income has been a perennial topic of debate in Congress.
Capital gains income is often discussed as if it were somehow different from other
forms of income. Yet, in economic terms, capital gains income is essentially no
different from any other form of income from capital, such as interest or dividend
income. A capital gain or loss is the result of a sale or exchange of a capital asset.
If the asset is sold for a higher price than its acquisition price, then the transaction
produces a capital gain. If an asset is sold for a lower price than its acquisition price,
then the transaction produces a capital loss.
Current law’s treatment of capital gains differs from what would occur under a
theoretically pure income tax. Ideally, a tax consistent with a theoretically correct
measure of income would be assessed on real (inflation-adjusted) income when that
income accrues to the taxpayer. Conversely, real losses should be deducted as they
accrue to the taxpayer. In addition, economic theory indicates that any real
appreciation in the value of capital assets given as gifts or bequests should be subject
to tax at the time of transfer to the extent it was not taxed as it accrued. Under the
current income tax, however, nominal (non-inflation adjusted) capital gains income
is taxed when it is realized (sold or exchanged) by the taxpayer. Capital losses (within
certain limits) are also deducted on a nominal basis when they are realized by the
taxpayer. Currently, the untaxed appreciation in the value of capital assets transferred
at death is not subject to tax.
Under current law, capital assets are separated into four categories. Assets that
have been held for 12 months or less are considered short-term assets. Assets that
have been held longer than 12 months are considered long-term assets. Collectibles
(art work, antiques, coins, stamps, etc.) are the third category of assets and the fourth
category of capital gains assets includes the portion of gain attributable to previously
taken depreciation deductions on section 1250 property (depreciable real estate).
Short-term capital gains are taxed at regular income tax rates. Long-term capital
gains are taxed at a maximum tax rate of 20%. The tax rate is 10% for long-term
gains that would have been taxed at a 15% regular tax rate. Collectibles held longer
than 12 months are taxed at 28%. The un-recaptured section 1250 gain attributable
to depreciation deductions is taxed at a maximum tax rate of 25%.
Effective for taxable years beginning in 2001, assets that have been held for at
least five years and would have been taxed at a 10% tax rate will be taxed at an 8%
tax rate. For assets which are held more than five years and whose holding period
begins after December 31, 2000, the maximum tax rate will be 18% rather than 20%.
Net capital losses are deductible against up to $3,000 of ordinary income, that is,
non-capital gain income. Any portion of the net loss in excess of the $3,000 limit can
be carried forward and used to offset gains in succeeding tax years. Excess net losses
can be carried forward indefinitely and without limit on the amount of losses that can
be carried forward.


8Authored by Gregg Esenwein, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance
Division.

Under current law, taxpayers are allowed to exclude from taxable income up to
$500,000 ($250,000 in the case of single returns) of the gain from the sale of their
principal residences. To qualify the taxpayer must have owned and occupied the
residence for at least two of the previous five years prior to the date of sale. Under
current law, capital gains transferred at time of death are not subject to tax. On
transfer at death, the basis of the asset (original cost plus changes in the value due to
improvements or depreciation) is stepped up to the market value of the asset on the
date of death.
Tax Treatment of Savings
The appropriate tax treatment of saving has been one of the most prominent tax
policy debates in recent decades, continuing into the 106th Congress. It subsumes
such topics as individual retirement accounts (IRAs), capital gains taxes, investment
incentives, and corporate income taxes, to list just a few of its particular incarnations.
The issue of savings has links to both economic performance and equity, which has
helped make it controversial. An increased saving rate generally increases the
country’s capital stock, which in turn makes possible higher economic growth and a
higher standard of living in the future. If tax incentives can boost saving, targeted tax
cuts may thus be able to boost economic growth. On the other hand, income from
investments is a higher proportion of income at higher income levels; tax benefits for
saving thus reduce the progressivity of the tax system.
Economics suggests that the efficacy of tax incentives for saving depends heavily
on how responsive individuals’ savings rates are to changes in the rate of return to
saving, after taxes. If individuals respond to tax incentives by increasing their saving,
tax benefits may be an effective tool for increasing economic growth. On the other
hand, if saving is unresponsive to targeted tax cuts, their efficacy is questionable.
Unhelpfully, economic theory provides no clear answer and instead identifies two
countervailing effects of tax incentives for saving. One effect (known as the
substitution effect) leads individuals to save more because the aftertax rate of return
has increased; a second effect (the income effect) works in the opposite direction,
because a tax cut enables an individual to reach a given savings target with a lower
savings rate.
The ambiguity of economic theory in this case places an additional burden of
proof on empirical evidence, and there have indeed been a plentitude of statistical
studies. But taken as a group, these studies too produce no clear answer; some find
a positive and significant relationship between tax incentives and saving — that is,
they find that targeted tax cuts increase saving. Other studies find no relationship, and
still others find a negative relationship. Thus, the impact of taxes on saving is
unproved. However, even if individuals were to respond positively to savings
incentives, that does not necessarily mean incentives are good economic policy.
First, what matters for economic growth is not simply private saving but national
saving — that is, the private saving rate minus any government dissaving by means
of a budget deficit. Thus, the effect of tax cuts for saving in reducing government tax
revenue may at least partly offset any positive effect they may have on private saving.
Second, even though increased saving produces higher standards of living in the
future, a tax-induced distortion that increases saving may not actually increase
economic welfare. Absent market failures, economic theory suggests a tax is more



efficient the less it changes behavior. And if saving is unresponsive to tax changes,
it may be less damaging to economic welfare than alternative sources of tax revenue.
Again, however, evidence on the responsiveness of saving is conflicting. Indeed, this
summarizes what economics has to say about tax incentives for saving: theory and
evidence on the efficacy of savings incentives is ambiguous and conflicting.
Tax benefits for saving in the current tax code are numerous. Among the most
prominent are individual retirement account (IRAs), 401(k) retirement savings plans
and other qualified employer-sponsored retirement plans, life insurance policies and
annuities, qualified state tuition programs, and medical savings accounts (MSAs). In
addition, the favorable tax treatment of owner-occupied housing can be thought of
as a saving incentive, as can the reduced tax rates for capital gains under the
individual income tax.
Tobacco Taxes9
The Balanced Budget Act of 1997 (the BBA; PL. 105-33) provided a substantial
increase in the federal excise tax on tobacco products. Beginning in 2000, the BBA
provided a 10-cent per pack increase in the federal excise tax on cigarettes, thus
raising the tax from prior law’s 24 cents per pack to 34 cents; the act increased taxes
on other tobacco products — for example, cigars, chewing tobacco, snuff, and pipe
tobacco — by the same proportion. Effective in 2002, the BBA scheduled an increase
in the tax by an additional 5 cents per pack, and a proportional increase in the other
tobacco taxes.
A tentative tobacco settlement plan negotiated between the states and the
tobacco industry, which would provide limits on future lawsuits in exchange for
payments and other restrictions on the industry, led to a number of legislative
proposals in the 105th Congress, including implementation of a tobacco settlement
under federal law with a per pack fee similar to an excise tax. The Administration
also proposed to raise $65.5 billion in revenue over five years (without specifying the
exact collection method), amounting to about 54 cents per pack. The tobacco bill
was not adopted. On November 17, 1998, the tobacco companies reached an
independent agreement with most states for payments that amount to about 35 cents
per pack. President Clinton proposed a substantial increase in the cigarette tax in both
his FY2000 and FY2001 budgets. The proposal has not been adopted.
Fundamental Tax Reform Proposals (Including Flat Tax
Plans)10
The idea of replacing our current income tax system with a “flat-rate tax”
continued to receive congressional interest in 2000. Although often referred to as
“flat-rate taxes,” many of the current proposals go much further than merely adopting


9Authored by Jane G. Gravelle, Senior Specialist in Economic Policy, Government and
Finance Division.
10Authored by James M. Bickley, Specialist in Public Finance, Government and Finance
Division.

a flat-rate tax structure. Some involve significant income tax base-broadening while
others entail changing the tax base from income to consumption. Most of the recent
tax reform proposals (the Armey, Shelby, Domenici/Nunn, English, Specter, Lugar,
Tauzin, Linder, Souder, Gramm, Faircloth, and Largent/Hutchinson plans) would
change the tax base from income to consumption. Others are not consumption tax
proposals. Representative Gephardt would keep income as the tax base but broaden
the base and lower the tax rates. Representative Crane’s proposal would levy a tax
on the earned income of each individual as a replacement for the current individual
income tax, corporate income tax, and estate and gift taxes. Former Representative
Snowbarger’s proposal would permit each taxpayer to choose between the current
individual income tax return and an alternative individual tax return with a flat rate.
Senator Dorgan’s proposal would allow most taxpayers to choose between the
current individual tax system and his “shortcut” tax plan under which taxes withheld
would equal the employee’s tax liability.
The flat tax controversy has focused on shifting from the present system, which
is predominantly an income tax system, to a consumption tax system as a way to raise
the savings rate, improve economic efficiency, and simplify the tax system. There is,
however, no conclusive empirical evidence that a consumption tax will or will not
increase the personal savings rate and consequently the level of national savings.
Highly stylized life-cycle models show that a consumption tax would cause a
substantial increase in the savings rate, but these models are controversial because of
their idealized assumptions. To raise the same amount of tax revenue, a
consumption-based tax would require higher marginal tax rates than would an income
tax (since consumption is smaller than income). Distortions caused by these higher
marginal rates could offset (or even exceed) other advantages of the consumption tax.
Hence, whether an income tax system or a consumption tax system is more efficient
is unknown.
Proponents of some flat tax proposals argue that integration of the current
corporate and individual income taxes as well as simple returns would result from a
consumption tax. The current income tax system is complex. The federal tax code
and the federal tax regulations are lengthy and continue to expand. However, in tax
year 1997, approximately 70% of individual taxpayers took the standard deduction,
which made complexity less relevant. Finally, some argue that it is unfair to compare
the current income tax system with an uncomplicated, “pure” consumption tax that
could become complicated by the time it is enacted.
It has been argued that some flat tax proposals would reduce the
balance-of-trade deficit since imports would be taxed but the tax would be rebatable
on exports. Economic theory, however, suggests that border tax adjustments have
no effect on the balance-of-trade because the balance-of-trade is a function of
international capital flows; border tax adjustments would be offset by exchange rate
adjustments.
The United States is the only developed country without a broad-based
consumption tax at the national level. Other developed nations have adopted
broad-based consumption taxes, but as adjuncts rather than as replacements for their
income based taxes.