Comparison of Tax Incentives for Domestic Manufacturing: 108th Congress

CRS Report for Congress
Comparison of Tax Incentives for Domestic
th
Manufacturing: 108 Congress
Updated January 25, 2005
Jane G. Gravelle
Senior Specialist in Economic Policy
Government and Finance Division


Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

Comparison of Tax Incentives for Domestic
Manufacturing: 108th Congress
Summary
Several tax bills were introduced in the 108th Congress to eliminate the
extraterritorial income (ETI) provision of the U.S. tax code that has been found to
contravene trade agreement restrictions against export subsidies by the World Trade
Organization (WTO). These bills contained different types of offsetting tax cuts for
domestic manufacturing. An early bill, H.R. 1769 (Crane and Rangel), would have
allowed a percentage reduction of the corporate tax rate proportional to the domestic
share of total output. (A similar bill, S. 970, was sponsored by Senator Hollings.) An
initial version of H.R. 2896, sponsored by Ways and Means Chairman Thomas would
have provided accelerated depreciation for manufacturing equipment (a similar bill,
S. 1475, was sponsored by Senator Hatch), although that provision was replaced by
a reduction in the top corporate tax rate on manufacturing in a later version of the
bill. The tax rate reduction is in H.R. 4520, the current bill passed by the House on
June 17, 2004. S. 1637, originally sponsored by Senate Finance Committee
Chairman Grassley and Ranking Member Baucus, and passed by the Senate on May
11, 2004, would have provided a rate cut similar to that in H.R. 1769. It would have
incorporated, but then phased out, the provision adjusting the cut for the share of
production that is domestic. This bill also contained a number of other provisions.
H.R. 4250, as enacted, followed the Senate version, but with the House’s expanded
definition of manufacturing.
Although the overall revenue cost of the rate cuts was larger than the effect of
accelerated depreciation initially proposed in H.R. 2896, the provisions would have
had about the same magnitude of effects on manufacturing tax burdens on new
investment, reducing them by about 4%. The small revenue cost of accelerated
depreciation could have produced a similar incentive effect, because it would not
benefit the return to existing capital. These incentive effects would have more than
offset the lost benefit from the repeal of ETI. However, the approach in H.R. 1769
would have had a more certain and larger effect on encouraging domestic investment
in manufacturing. Additional domestic investment would have had both a direct tax
benefit effect and an indirect effect through increasing the ratio of domestic to world
production.
Within manufacturing, accelerated depreciation tends to introduce distortions
across asset type, while rate reductions, particularly if confined to corporate rates,
reduce distortions between debt and equity and corporate and noncorporate
investment. Accelerated depreciation and rate cuts have quite different implications
for tax administration and compliance. Although any provision that singles out an
activity to favor will encounter administrative costs in ascertaining the qualified
activities, accelerated depreciation applied to manufacturing assets was probably
feasible to administer without a great deal of additional cost. However, a rate
reduction for a specific activity potentially could have led to significant increases in
these costs, as firms that operate in many different activities attempt to claim
manufacturing status and to transfer taxable income into their manufacturing
activities through distortions in within-company transfer prices and misallocations
of deductions and passive income. This report will not be updated.



Contents
Descriptions of the Proposals.........................................2
H.R. 1769 ...................................................2
H.R. 2896....................................................2
H.R. 4520....................................................3
S. 1637......................................................4
Magnitude of Effects on Domestic Manufacturing Investment...............5
Other Effects on the Allocation of Capital...............................7
Issues of Administration and Compliance...............................7
Conclusion .......................................................9
Appendix .......................................................10



Comparison of Tax Incentives for Domestic
th
Manufacturing: 108 Congress
Several bills were introduced in the 108th Congress which would have
eliminated the extraterritorial income tax (ETI) provision that has been found to
contravene trade agreement restrictions against export subsidies by the World Trade
0rganization (WTO). Each bill included other provisions, in some cases to offset the
revenue gain from the provision with a tax cut, and in others to go beyond the offset
to provide an overall net tax reduction.1 Each bill had a provision that was
specifically focused on manufacturing and was either explicitly limited to or would
in effect be largely focused on domestic manufacturing. The argument for providing
an offsetting benefit to manufacturing was that the burden of the repeal of the ETI
largely falls on the manufacture of goods in the United States, and in some ways the
provision of benefits to domestic manufacturing was the closest way to provide
general tax cuts to the firms that lose benefits. In addition, arguments were made that
losing the export subsidy would discourage domestic production, and this incentive
was needed to offset the effects of eliminating the ETI.
The enacted provision of this legislation (H.R. 4520), following the passage of
the Senate’s version (then S. 1637) and the House bill (H.R. 4520) followed the
Senate version, which allowed a deduction and would cover unincorporated firms as
well as corporations. However, the proposal contained the broader definition of
manufacturing in the House bill which included oil and gas extraction, utilities,
construction, and electricity.
The remainder of this report discusses the provisions in these two versions of
the subsidy as well as some of the issues surrounding alternative methods of
providing a manufacturing subsidy.
In the case of the Crane-Rangel bill (H.R. 1769); the Grassley-Baucus bill (S.
1637), which was reported out of the Senate Finance Committee on October 1; and
the second version of H.R. 2896 (Thomas), reported out of the Ways and Means
Committee on October 28, this tax benefit was provided through a rate reduction (in
the form of a deduction in H.R. 1769 and S. 1637 through a cut in the top corporate
rate in H.R. 2896). H.R. 4520, passed by the House, also contained the
manufacturing rate cut. In the case of the initial version of Thomas bill (H.R. 2896),
the manufacturing tax benefit was provided via a depreciation deduction. The
Hollings (S. 970) bill was identical to H.R. 1769 and the Hatch (S. 1475) bill was
similar in many respects to the initial version of H.R. 2896. However, the President
did not include such a proposal in his budget proposals.


1 See CRS Report RL32066, Taxes, Exports, and International Investment: Proposals in
the 108th Congress, by David Brumbaugh for additional analysis of these proposals.

A floor amendment during consideration of S. 1637 that proposed to allow a
credit for wages in manufacturing rather than a rate reduction was defeated on May

5, 2004. The final legislation followed S. 1637.


This report focuses on comparing the manufacturing provisions. It begins with
a brief description of the provisions in each of the four bills, and proceeds with an
analysis of the general magnitude of the effect on investment incentives, the
allocational effects across types of investment, and issues of administration and
compliance.
Descriptions of the Proposals
While H.R. 1769 focused on repealing the ETI and offsetting the gain with a
manufacturer’s subsidy, H.R. 2869, S. 1637, and H.R. 4520 were much broader, with
the ETI repeal and the manufacturing tax benefit only a part of the bill.
While this paper focuses on comparing the domestic manufacturing provisions,
this section briefly discusses other provisions that will be referred to in the discussion
of allocational effects.
H.R. 1769
H.R. 1769 proposed to offset the revenue loss from the repeal of ETI with a
deduction of up to 10% of taxable income from domestic production. The deduction
would be multiplied by the share of the total business that is domestic. Thus, if the
capital output ratio were the same in the United States as abroad, the deduction for
total income would be multiplied by the share domestic squared. If a firm had 50%
of its output domestic, the effective deduction rate for domestic income would be

5%, and the effective deduction overall would be 2.5% (10% X(0.5)2).


H.R. 2896
An earlier version of H.R. 2896 contained a provision to allow accelerated
depreciation for manufacturing equipment and did not contain a manufacturing tax
reduction.2


2 The initial version of H.R. 2896 proposed a series of temporary and permanent provisions
to offset the repeal of ETI. (which gained $49 billion). The depreciation provision cost $35
billion; other provisions would have limited benefits for domestic manufacturing or are
temporary. The largest set of tax cuts was a series of provisions benefitting earnings from
foreign investment which amount to $80 to $90 billion (the higher number includes an $11.3
billion expansion of the alternative minimum tax that would significantly benefit foreign
source income); all provisions were permanent with the exception of a temporary provision
costing $3 billion to provide a tax holiday for the repatriation of earnings from abroad. The
bill also contained $24 billion in provisions that benefitted smaller and medium sized
businesses, with a $2 billion a temporary provision expanding equipment expensing; most
of the cost ($19.5 billion) would reduce corporate tax rates for smaller firms. The remaining
(continued...)

H.R. 2896 proposed a series of temporary and permanent provisions to offset
the phased out repeal of ETI, which would gain $43.1 billion over 2004-2013. (All
revenue estimates mentioned in this report refer to a 10-year period unless otherwise
noted). For domestic manufacturing and certain other production activities, the top
corporate tax rate would have been lowered from 35% to (initially) 34% and then
32% in 2006 and after; this provision would have cost $61.1 billion. There were a
number of other tax cuts and tax increases in the bill, but most of them would have
had limited benefits for domestic manufacturing or are temporary.
The largest set of tax cuts in the bill was a series of provisions benefitting
earnings from foreign investment, which would have amounted to $39.2 billion,
including a $3 billion provision to allow a more complete offset of foreign tax credits
losses against the alternative minimum tax (AMT). These provisions could have
provided tax cuts for firms that manufacture in the U.S. and also manufacture abroad,
but their incentive effects would have been to discourage domestic production.
Another $4.7 billion was associated with allowing more net operating losses against
the AMT and $1 billion in exempting smaller firms.
The bill also contained some additional provisions that would have benefitted
smaller and medium sized businesses, amounting to $18.4 billion, with a $2 billion
temporary provision expanding equipment expensing. Most of the cost would have
reduced corporate tax rates on taxable income, initially on income below $1 million
and eventually below $20 million. Benefits for Subchapter S corporations
(incorporated firms treated as partnerships for tax purposes) would have amounted
to $1.3 billion. (Since most manufacturing is carried out by large firms, these
benefits were unlikely to be very important to the industry.) A provision providing
more rapid depreciation for leasehold improvements and restaurants for a temporary
period, amounting to about $2.1 billion, would have benefitted smaller firms and
would not have benefitted domestic manufacturing. $1.1 billion was associated with
employee benefits, and about $1 billion was associated with a series of miscellaneous
business provisions. The bill also would have raised about $9 billion from tax shelter
provisions and $16 billion from customs fees.
H.R. 4520
H.R. 4520 proposed a series of temporary and permanent provisions to offset
the phased out repeal of ETI, which would gain $49.6 billion over 2004-2014. (All
revenue estimates in this section refer to that 11-year period). For domestic
manufacturing and certain other production activities, the top corporate tax rate


2 (...continued)
provisions involve removing more small firms from coverage of the AMT and benefits for
Subchapter S corporations (incorporated firms treated as partnerships for tax purposes) ;a
provision providing more rapid depreciation for leasehold improvements and restaurants
(about $8 billion); a one-year extension of bonus depreciation ($12 billion), an extension
of the R&D credit ($23 billion); an extension of net operating loss carryforwards ($5
billion); a general provision expanding depreciation for purposes of the AMT and tax
provisions that raise revenues by about $9 billion by addressing tax shelters. (About $12
billion is raised by customs fees). Many of these provisions were retained in the revised
version of the bill.

would have been lowered from 35% to (initially) 34% and then 32% in 2007 and
after; this provision would have cost $63.6 billion. There were a number of other tax
cuts and tax increases in the bill, but most of them would have limited benefits for
domestic manufacturing or are temporary.
Many of the other provisions of H.R. 4520 were similar to those in H.R. 2896.
Provisions affecting earnings on foreign source income were smaller ($33.1 billion
including a $3.4 billion offset for the foreign tax credit against the alternative
minimum tax). The bill also included a $3.5 billion cost to allow a temporary lower
tax on repatriation of foreign dividends. There was no general net operating
provision, although there was one for small business. For small firms, extension of
expensing for small firms ($1 billion), other rate cuts ($14.9 billion ) and provisions
for Subchapter S firms ($1.3 billion) were retained, as was depreciation for
leaseholds and restaurants ($2.3 billion). The bill also contained $0.9 billion of
miscellaneous reductions, $0.5 billion excise tax reductions, and a $6.1 billion
benefit for alcohol fuels.
H.R. 4520 also extended expiring provisions ($14 billion) and allowed a
temporary deduction for state and local sales taxes ($3.6 billion for 2005 and 2006).
Tax shelter provisions were much more extensive ($40.7 billion), due largely to the
inclusion of a leasing provisions (and increasing expectations of revenue gains from
restricting leasing), although an earnings stripping provision was dropped. Customs
fees would have raised $18.6 billion.
S. 1637
This bill would have provided a repeal of the ETI raising $55.7 billion in
revenue, which would have been offset by approximately $10 billion in transition
relief. It would have been offset by a deduction of 9% of the profits from U.S.
domestic manufacturing production, costing $45.6 billion. (This deduction would
have reduced the rate from 35% to 31.85%). This deduction would have been phased
in and initially would have been affected by the domestic share of worldwide
production as in H.R. 1769 (but that effect would have been eliminated in the long
run).
The initial bill also contained some benefits for income from overseas
investment, but in a much smaller amount of $7.1 billion, which included $3.8 billion
for a temporary provision allowing tax free repatriation of foreign source income.
Additional provisions added prior to markup raised the total from $7 billion to $25.5
billion, with an additional $11.3 billion added during markup, for a total of $38
billion. Thus, the permanent provisions for foreign investment were about the same
size as in H.R. 2896 (but considerably smaller than the provisions in the initial
version). There were also numerous provisions to raise revenue, including some that
addressed tax shelters (and in some cases these tax shelters were related to foreign
activities); these amounted to $25 billion before markup with another $30 billion
added during mark-up.
Additional provisions added before markup expanded the manufacturing
deduction largely by extending it to unincorporated businesses and to oil refining and
timber at a cost of $14.1 billion and including a mixture of other minor tax benefits,



including benefits for films and timber costing about $3 billion. $14 billion of other
tax cuts were added during mark-up.
A number of amendments were considered during the debate on the Senate
floor; one that would have replaced the rate reduction for manufacturing with a wage
credit was defeated on May 5, 2004.
On the Senate floor, the manufacturers’ provision was extended to film-making.
A number of other provisions were adopted relating largely to tax shelter provisions.
The final bill as enacted into law (H.R. 4520) followed the approach in S. 1637,
but expanded coverage to more types of production, including property
manufactured, produced, grown or extracted within the United States. Domestic
film, energy, and construction, and engineering and architectural services are
specifically included, although the services must be produced in the United States for
construction projects located in the United States. The law specifically excludes the
sale of food and beverages prepared at a retail establishment; transmission and
distribution of electricity, gas, and water; and receipts from property leased, licensed,
or rented to a related party. The deduction is limited to 50% of wages and therefore
is not available to sole proprietors.
Magnitude of Effects on Domestic
Manufacturing Investment
This section compares the rate reductions with each other and with accelerated
depreciation. While the revenue costs discussed above provide some notion of the
magnitude of effects of the tax provisions, they cannot easily be compared. Rate
reductions occur each year in about the same amounts but accelerated depreciation
confers its benefits primarily in timing effects.
The rate reductions in S. 1637 and H.R. 4520 were phased in. At the same time,
the initial years of the accelerated depreciation deductions in the original version of
H.R. 2896 occurred in periods when bonus depreciation would have been in effect;
the revenue cost was larger without bonus depreciation than with it. Overall,
however, the rate reduction in S. 1637 provided a larger tax benefit during the 10-
year revenue estimating period and beyond than the accelerated depreciation
deduction.
The rate reduction in S. 1637 compensated for the effect of the loss of the export
subsidy in manufacturing as a whole (although not necessarily for very export
intensive firms). The repeal of ETI should have reduced exports, which were largely
manufacturing, and the domestic manufacturing subsidies that offset it probably
would have increased overall domestic manufacturing in the long run since the
annual revenue cost in the last year for the manufacturing deduction was larger than
the revenue gain from repealing ETI (a gain in 2013 of $7 billion compared to a loss
from $10 billion from the original bill and another $2 billion from the additions).
Since both the export deduction and the manufacturing deduction were of the same
type (a reduction in current income taxes), the larger size of the manufacturing



incentive suggested that it more than compensated for the additional burdens. The
rate reduction in H.R. 2896 was slightly smaller, at $9 billion but still larger than the
ETI repeal.
The composition of manufacturing will shift somewhat, however, because firms
with a lot of export business will suffer relative to firms with little export business.
The size of the cash flow effects does not mean that the overall incentive to
invest in domestic manufacturing is smaller than the original accelerated depreciation
provisions. Rate reductions reduce the return to the existing stock of assets, while
accelerated depreciation benefits only investment (net and replacement). To have the
same incentive effect a rate reduction would cost more in present value terms than
accelerated depreciation.
There is a way, however, to assess the general magnitude of the effects of these
provisions, at least in terms of the incentives provided to domestic investment.
Calculations in a CRS report3 indicate that the initial depreciation provision in H.R.
2896 and the rate reductions in manufacturing in S. 1637 and H.R. 1769 would have
had about the same overall magnitude of benefits for manufacturing, reducing the
effective tax rate overall by about 1.5 percentage points (assuming no bonus
depreciation). Since corporate investment is subject to a current rate of around 40%,
this reduction is about a 4% reduction. It is small, but so is the overall effect of
repealing ETI.
The provisions of H.R. 1769 would have had a more pronounced effect on the
provision of incentives to invest in domestic manufacturing than the other two bills,
for two reasons. First, because the subsidy is dependent on the domestic share of
value added, an increase in domestic investment has two effects on the tax benefit:
the direct effect of increase in domestic taxable income, and the indirect effect of
increasing the domestic share. (See Appendix for a discussion.) Moreover, there is
a disincentive to invest abroad. There is a temporary effect in S. 1637 of this type as
well. Making an incentive dependent on the domestic share of output is more
feasible with a rate reduction than with accelerated depreciation.
This analysis looks at the manufacturing subsidy in isolation. The relative effect
of H.R. 1769 on encouraging substitution of domestic for foreign investment
compared to the other bills could be greater when considering the benefits for foreign
source investment in S. 1637 and H.R. 2896. Indeed, judging from revenue losses
associated with foreign source income, while H.R. 1769 would offset (and perhaps
slightly more than offset) the discouraging of domestic production from the export
subsidies, S. 1637 and H.R. 2896 could have encouraged an outflow of capital.
Some of the foreign provisions, however, because of the way they are structured,
encourage domestic investment, so that conclusion is unclear.
Note also that these calculations assume no bonus depreciation. The
independent effects of accelerated depreciation with bonus depreciation already in


3 CRS Report RL32099, Corporate Income Tax Revisions and Effective Tax Rates, by Jane
G. Gravelle.

place are about 60% as large. The effects are also slightly smaller for the rate
reductions. While bonus depreciation has expired, it is possible that such provisions
could be reinstated in the President’s proposed fundamental tax reform plan.
Of course, there is an additional policy question: whether it is desirable to
subsidize domestic or foreign production. Under a common standard used by
economists to judge world wide economic efficiency (which suggests that U.S.-
owned capital is allocated most efficiently when rates of return are equated in both
places) the direction of change to increase economic efficiency depends on the extent
to which foreign source income is undertaxed relative to U.S. income (as it is in low
tax countries) or overtaxed (as it is in high tax countries). If the objective is to
maximize U.S. economic welfare, it is better to encourage domestic investment in
large part because taxes on returns to domestic investment accrue to the U.S.
Treasury, while taxes on returns to foreign source investment may largely accrue to
foreign governments. (This analysis assumes that foreign governments do not
retaliate against U.S. policies to discourage capital outflow).
There is also a distributional effect: while tax subsidies benefit owners of capital
in general, inducing investment in the United States tends to benefit domestic
workers, but reduces earnings of foreign workers, while the opposite occurs when
investment is encouraged to move abroad.
Other Effects on the Allocation of Capital
The alternative approaches — accelerated depreciation vs. rate reduction —
would have other effects as well. The accelerated depreciation provisions were
restricted to equipment and were available for both debt and equity; therefore, within
the manufacturing sector, they introduced distortions in the allocation of the capital
stock without reducing distortions between debt and equity finance. Rate cuts also
reduced distortions between corporate and non-corporate sectors, although there is
relatively little non-corporate manufacturing. (The rate reduction in H.R. 1769,
which is limited to corporations, would reduce this distortion more.) Thus, based on
more neutral taxation of types of investments and finance within the manufacturing
sector, the rate reduction is more neutral than accelerated depreciation.
Accelerated depreciation, however, reduced effective tax rates more per dollar
of revenue loss and therefore was a more effective method of reducing the overall
distortion between present and future consumption (because it did not benefit
existing capital).
Issues of Administration and Compliance
Carving out a special tax provision for a particular industry will create some
significant administrative costs — both in the definition of the favored activity and
the allocation of income for diversified firms.



No definition of the favored activity can be drawn that will not give rise to some
disputes about what activities are or are not manufacturing. State experience with
manufacturing exemptions is instructive in showing the types of disputes that may
arise. For example, recent cases dealt with whether the mixing of paint in a retail
store was manufacturing, how to determine the extent to which newspapers involve
manufacturing (the printing of the paper is manufacturing, but what about the
gathering and processing of content?), and the extent to which activities such as
broadcasting, on-site pizza dough making in a restaurant, brewing beer for a brew
pub, and blending sand qualified as manufacturing.4 These problems occur with both
accelerated depreciation for manufacturing equipment and with a special tax rate on
manufacturing profits, although they would probably be somewhat more troubling
with a rate reduction because capital intensity in machinery use is probably more
associated with traditional manufacturing activities where little dispute would arise.
A second, and perhaps more serious problem arises with the special rate
reduction. Many firms operate in manufacturing and in other types of business as
well. They may be firms with some amount of vertical integration (e.g. operating
related wholesale and retail sales, or finance, businesses). Firms may also operate
different types of businesses, an approach that reduces risk. And some activities
may have a manufacturing and a non-manufacturing element (such as the newspaper
example discussed above). These different businesses may be branches of the same
entity, or may be separately incorporated affiliates. Because of the variety of
activities, one cannot simply allow any firm that engages in manufacturing to take
a deduction for its taxable income without allocating income to the manufacturing
activity. In many cases, neither firms nor the IRS have existing experience in
allocation of income and deductions across activities.
This problem of allocation of income has been a serious and longstanding
problem in our international tax system, where, because we do not currently tax
foreign source income and do not allow unlimited foreign tax credits, firms have an
incentive to allocate income to the areas that minimize their tax liability. Two
methods are used to achieve this effect. First, when domestic and foreign entities buy
products from each other, taxable income will be affected by the intercompany price
charged — an issue referred to as transfer pricing. Tax rules require an arm’s length
price (the price that would be charged by related parties) but this arm’s length price
is observable only if the items are traded in a general market and in many cases such
comparables do not exist. Secondly, the firm can attempt to allocate deductions and
other payments, such as interest, rents, royalties, and overhead costs, in a way to
minimize taxable income in high tax jurisdictions. A great deal of time and effort on
the part of taxpayers, the Internal Revenue Service, and the courts is devoted to
adjudicating these issues.
There is a contrast between the complexity of accelerated depreciation versus
a rate reduction, therefore, with respect to administrative costs. While carving out a
special depreciation rule is somewhat complicated, the present depreciation system
is actually linked to a more detailed underlying depreciation schedule where many
assets are differentiated not according to type, but according to the industry in which


4 These cases were provided by Matt Tomalis of the Federation of Tax Administrators.

they are used. Moreover, for manufacturing equipment, its use is relatively clear in
most cases. There are assets used across industries (e.g., computers, furniture and
fixtures) which were not classified by industry but by type (often part of overhead
costs) that could present a problem.
In the case of a deduction for taxable income, however, all of the issues
associated with transfer pricing and the allocation of passive income and deductions
that have created such administrative difficulties in the international tax system
would occur in the domestic U.S. economy. The rate reduction approach, therefore,
would be more costly to administer and comply with than the accelerated
depreciation deductions.
Conclusion
This analysis suggests that the rate reduction for manufacturing approach in S.
1637 and the current version of H.R. 2896, while costing more revenue than the
accelerated depreciation for manufacturing equipment in the initial version of H.R.
2896 and other bills, has about the same effect on the overall cost of capital and the
incentive to invest abroad. The rate reduction in H.R. 1769 has the larger effect
because it is multiplied by the ratio of domestic to total output, a feature that can be
added to a rate reduction approach easily, but not to an accelerated depreciation
approach. Within the manufacturing sector, the rate reduction approach is more
neutral and reduces other distortions, particularly if confined to a corporate rate
reduction. However, the rate reduction raises much more serious issues with respect
to administration and compliance than does the accelerated depreciation provision.



Appendix
The benefit, B, of the tax rate provision is, in the case of S. 1637:
(1) B = grtKD
where g is the percentage deduction, t is the tax rate, r is the rate of return and KD is the
capital stock. For purposes of a small change we can hold the return fixed (one could also
derive the effects by expressing benefits as B = gt(QD-wLD), where QD is output and LD is
the labor supply, and the last term in parentheses is profits). This example ignores debt
finance.
In the case of H.R. 1769, the benefit is:
(2) B = grtKD (D/(F+D))
where D is the amount of domestic production and F is foreign production.
Converting to logs and differentiating these equations, which produces
percentage changes, holding g, r and t constant, in the case of S. 1637, and with a hat
(^) denoting percentage change:
^ ^(3) B = K
D
The magnitude of the effects in H.R. 1769 depend on two issues. First, does the
analysis involve examining the substitution of capital between domestic and foreign
uses, holding the total capital stock fixed, or, instead simply involve an additional
amount of capital added. Secondly, is the addition of capital accompanied by the
same percentage addition of other inputs such as labor (referred to as a fixed
technology case) or are other factors fixed. (The truth probably lies somewhere in
the middle.)
In the case of H.R. 1769, and assuming that fixed technology of production, so
that a percentage change in capital stock leads to a percentage change in output, and
also assuming that capital invested in the United States is shifted from abroad (total
capital stock is fixed)
^ ^ ^ ^(4) B = K + D = 2K
D D
In this case the effect is twice as large for H.R. 1769.
If the domestic investment adds to the total capital stock the effect is
^ ^ ^ ^(5) B = K+ D (F/(F+D) = K(1+F/(F+D))
D D
In this case, the incentive to invest domestically is actually greater for firms with a
large amount of foreign activity.



An investment abroad in isolation, denoting foreign capital as KF, will lead to a
reduction in the benefit:
^ ^ (6) B = - (F/(F+D)) K
F
(and if we measure the change in foreign capital as a percent of domestic capital, the
multiplicative term in (6) will be D/(F+D)).
If capital expands with no matching expansion of other inputs, such as labor, the
additional effects will multiplied by the capital share of income. That is, a
substitution will lead to a new version of equation (4):
^ ^ ^ ^(7) B = K+ aD = (1+a)K
D D
where a is the share of capital income. Since a is typically about a third, the effect
of the exclusion which is multiplied by the share domestic is to provide an incentive
about 33% larger.
There are similar modifications of the effects in the other equations (5):
^ ^ ^ ^(8) B = K+ a D (F/(F+D) = K(1+aF/(F+D))
D D
and (6):
^ ^ (9) B = - a (F/(F+D)) K.


F