Aviation Congestion and Delay: System-Wide and New York-Area Issues







Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress



Aviation congestion and delay is an issue of long standing. Statistically, there was a significant
increase in congestion and delay throughout the national aviation system in 2007. The situation
has been especially noticeable at certain key airports, namely the New York region in general and
John F. Kennedy International Airport (JFK) in particular. The Department of Transportation
(DOT) and its operating agency, the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA), have promised to
take actions aimed at reducing congestion and delay both in the short and long terms. In the short
term, DOT is proposing to address the JFK situation through administrative and economic
measures that would likely restrict or otherwise provide for the allocation of flights into the
airport during specific periods of time.
In addition to the proposals likely to be made by DOT, there are other potential near-term fixes
that can be considered to add system-wide capacity to the aviation system. These include, but are
not limited to: airspace redesign, use of military airspace, and airspace flow control. Over the
longer term the FAA is primarily relying on modernization of the air traffic control system
through the Next Generation Air Transportation System (NGATS or NextGen) and the creation of
new airport infrastructure to provide major reductions in aviation congestion and delay, although
a recent FAA capacity needs study has concluded that these enhancements are needed
immediately, especially in the New York region.
Congress has taken an interest in this issue as growing concerns over airline service have
paralleled ongoing legislative action to reauthorize the activities of the FAA and the revenue
mechanisms for funding the operations of the national airspace system. The Bush Administration,
and especially Secretary of Transportation Peters, favor examining market mechanisms as a
means to pay for infrastructure operations, maintenance, and development in all transportation
modes. When the Administration submitted its proposals for FAA reauthorization in early 2007
(H.R. 1356/S. 1076), it included a pilot program to evaluate market-based mechanisms to relieve
congestion at up to 16 airports. The FAA proposal was not adopted in either the House (H.R.
2881) or Senate (S. 1300) reauthorization bills still under consideration at the end of 2007, but the
House bill contains provisions intended to help the FAA deal with congestion problems at specific
airports.
Regulation of the national air transportation system is legally the domain of the federal
government. The operation and ownership of airports, however, is provided primarily by regional,
state and local entities. Neither the FAA nor the DOT have, to date, attempted to develop and
impose a congestion pricing scheme on the local authorities. In the event that FAA should decide
to make such an attempt, it appears that there are several legal issues that may arise. This report
will be updated as warranted by DOT and congressional actions.






Air Carrier Delay Trends.................................................................................................................1
Causes of Air Carrier Delays...........................................................................................................3
Airline Scheduling and Equipage..............................................................................................4
Constraints on Airport and Air Traffic Control System Capacity.............................................7
Business Jets and Other High-Performance General Aviation Aircraft Operations..................9
Some Possible Near-Term Remedies for Reducing Air Traffic Congestion and Mitigating
Delays ......................................................................................................................... ................ 10
Airspace Redesign...................................................................................................................10
Opening of Military Airspace to Civilian Air Traffic..............................................................10
Ground Delay and Airspace Flow Programs and Other Congestion Management
Tools ...................................................................................................................................... 11
Technology and Procedural Changes......................................................................................12
Airline Upgauging...................................................................................................................13
Demand Management: Slot Controls and Congestion Pricing......................................................13
Slot Controls............................................................................................................................14
Antitrust Immunity............................................................................................................16
Congestion Pricing/Peak Period Pricing.................................................................................17
Aviation Infrastructure Pricing..........................................................................................17
U.S. and Non-U.S. Experience With Congestion Pricing.................................................18
Issues ................................................................................................................................. 20
Legal Issues...................................................................................................................................22
Federal Aviation Laws.............................................................................................................23
Airport’s Proprietary Powers...................................................................................................24
Previous Attempts to Impose “Congestion Pricing” Mechanisms....................................25
Potential Legal Issues Should FAA Impose Congestion Pricing......................................30
Figure 1. Annual System-Wide Air Carrier Flight Delays and Cancellations (1998-2007)............3
Figure 2. Causes of Air Carrier Flight Delays.................................................................................4
Figure 3. System-Wide Percent of Flights Arriving and Departing On Time as a Function
of the Time of Day (2006 Data)...................................................................................................5
Author Contact Information..........................................................................................................32





viation congestion and delay is an issue of long standing. Statistically, there was a
significant increase in congestion and delay throughout the national aviation system in

2007. The situation has been especially noticeable at certain key airports, namely the A


New York region in general and John F. Kennedy International Airport (JFK) in particular. The
Department of Transportation (DOT) and its operating agency, the Federal Aviation
Administration (FAA), have promised to take actions aimed at reducing congestion and delay
both in the short and long terms. In the short term, DOT is proposing to address the JFK situation
through administrative and economic measures that would likely restrict or otherwise provide for
the allocation of flights into the airport during specific periods of time. More detail on DOT’s 1
plans is expected to be available in the latter half of December 2007.
In addition to the proposals likely to be made by DOT, there are other potential near-term fixes
that can be considered to add system-wide capacity to the aviation system. These include, but are
not limited to: airspace redesign, use of military airspace, and airspace flow control. Over the
longer term the FAA is primarily relying on modernization of the air traffic control system
through the Next Generation Air Transportation System (NGATS or NextGen) and the creation of
new airport infrastructure to provide major reductions in aviation congestion and delay.
This report discusses the causes of congestion and delay in the current context. It also discusses
some technological and administrative mechanisms that might be employed to mitigate these
problems. This discussion is followed by an overview of demand management (economic)
remedies to congestion as they might be applied in an airport/airspace environment, and discusses
the rather limited historical experience with the use of these mechanisms. Finally, the report
concludes with a legal overview of how specific congestion remedies, in particular those
involving aviation system pricing, might be applied and administered.

Over the past four years, system-wide airline passenger volumes have continued to grow, now
surpassing pre-9/11 levels. Along with this growth, flight delays and cancellations have also
increased, and statistics indicate that the percentage of flights delayed 15 minutes or more in 2007
may surpass the prior record set in 2000. The percentage of cancelled flights is also up, although
not quite as high as the percentage of cancellations experienced in 1999, 2000, and 2001 (see
Figure 1). Some also point out that delay statistics alone do not tell the whole story. This is
because airlines have, in many cases, opted to lengthen scheduled flight times, particularly along 2
heavily congested and frequently delayed routes. A comparison of present day airline schedules
to 1997 schedules found that published trip times are about 10% higher than they were 10 years 3
ago. Additional schedule adjustments could be forthcoming and may further increase typical
travel times, particularly in response to recent Administration announcements that it would 4
consider operation of chronically delayed flights to constitute an “unfair and deceptive practice.”

1 Wall, Matthew L. & Belson, Ken. U.S. to Limit Flights at Kennedy. The New York Times. December 11, 2007. p.
A31.
2 See Scott McCartney,Why Flights Are Getting Longer,” The Wall Street Journal, May 29, 2007, p. D1.
3 Ibid.
4 “White House Unveils Plan to Ease Holiday Travel Congestion,Associated Press, November 15, 2007.



Despite airline schedule adjustments that have increased planned-for trip times, airline delays are
still ticking upward. As a consequence of this increase in delays, combined with airline schedule
padding and passengers factoring additional wait times at security screening checkpoints into
their travel plans, airline passenger trips are getting longer on average and travelers often face
more hassles. Consumer complaints and media coverage of air carrier service deficiencies and
cases of extensively delayed flights have put the specific issue of air carrier flight delays in the
spotlight during the summer of 2007. In response, the DOT has convened a task force consisting
of senior management to assess persisting problems with airline delays and consumer service, and
has convened a special aviation rulemaking committee (ARC), consisting of aviation stakeholders
representing airlines, airports, general aviation users, and airline consumers, to specifically
address delays and other airline service issues in the New York metropolitan area. Based on the
findings and recommendations of these groups, which are expected before the end of calendar
year 2007, the DOT intends to propose options to address and remedy airline delay and customer 5
service problems. Congress has taken a particular interest in this issue as these growing concerns
over airline service have paralleled ongoing legislative action to reauthorize the activities of the
FAA and the revenue mechanisms for funding the operations of the national airspace system.
While there are broad concerns over aviation congestion and delay at many of the nation’s busy
airports, there is particular concern regarding airline service and performance at major airports in
the New York metropolitan area where delay problems are the most acute. On-time arrival and
departure statistics for the past two years compiled by the DOT’s, Bureau of Transportation
Statistics (BTS) have consistently ranked the three New York metropolitan area commercial
passenger airports—Newark Liberty (EWR), John F. Kennedy International (JFK), and
LaGuardia (LGA)—at or near the bottom of the list among the busiest 32 airports in the United
States. From January 2007 through August 2007, about one out of every three flights arrived or
departed more than fifteen minutes late at these airports. Between January 2002 and September

2007 at these three airports, arrival and departure delays were typically around one hour in length.


At Newark Liberty Airport, where delays have consistently been the worst among busy U.S.
airports, departure delays averaged 67 minutes and arrivals delays averaged 73 minutes over the 6
time frame from September 2006 through September 2007. According to the FAA, over the
summer of 2007, 44% of all air delays experienced throughout the United States occurred in the 7
New York, New Jersey, and Philadelphia region. What’s more, there was a dramatic increase in
the percentage of flights cancelled at all three of these airports in 2007 compared to prior years.
From January through September 2007, JFK saw 3.18% of its flights cancelled, LGA had 4.81%
of its flights cancelled, and at EWR, 3.65% of scheduled passenger flights were cancelled. Not
only are these cancellation rates much higher than previous years, but they are also considerably
higher than the system-wide averages presented in Figure 1.

5 Remarks for the Honorable Mary Peters, Secretary of Transportation, Aviation Congestion Relief Plan, Media
Briefing, Washington, DC, September 27, 2007.
6 The times represent the average (mean) delay for arrivals and departures among flights that were delayed 15 minutes
or more.
7 Statement of Robert A. Sturgell, Acting Administrator, Testimony Before the House Committee on Transportation
and Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Aviation, On Airline Delays and Consumer Issues, September 26, 2007.





Figure 1. Annual System-Wide Air Carrier Flight Delays and Cancellations (1998-

2007)


Source: Bureau of Transportation Statistics.
Note: Statistics for 2007 cover 1/07 through 9/07.

While many travelers perceive that delays are frequently associated with weather, actual delays
directly attributable to severe weather conditions account for only a relatively small portion of
total system-wide delays (about 6% of all air carrier delays from June 2003 through August
2007). Rather, delays are most readily attributable to a combination of the current system’s
inability to cope with weather, congestion, and other factors affecting the efficient flow of traffic
at major airports and along crowded airways. These types of delays, referred to as national
aviation system delays, account for about 31% of all air carrier delays and are the types of delays
that the DOT believes can be remedied through investment in new technologies and more
efficient procedures for air traffic management. Other sources of delays include air carrier delays
arising from maintenance difficulties and inefficiencies in air carrier operations which account for
about one quarter (27%, to be exact) of all delays.





Figure 2. Causes of Air Carrier Flight Delays
(June 2003-September 2007)
Air Carrier Delay
27%
Aircraft Arriving Late
36%
Weather Delay
6%
Security Delay
< 1 %
National Aviation System
De l ay
31%
Source: CRS Analysis of Bureau of Transportation Statistics Delay Cause Summary Data.
Also, the cascading effects resulting from aircraft arriving late that cannot be turned around in
time to maintain outbound flight schedules account for 36% of all flight delays. However, the root
causes of initial schedule delays that produce these cascading delays throughout an operational
day can be primarily traced back to system inefficiencies and air carrier scheduling inefficiencies
and constraints. Despite heightened aviation security, security related delays have had a negligible
impact (less than 1% of flight delays) on air carrier operations (see Figure 2).
Analysis of airline schedule delays and cancellations across the entire system, and more
specifically at the three New York area airports, point to no one single cause, but rather a variety
of potential contributing factors. These factors can be grouped into three broad categories:
• Airline Scheduling and Equipage
• Constraints on Airport and Air Traffic Control System Capacity; and
• Business Jets and Other High-Performance General Aviation Aircraft Operations
The single leading cause of delays is the cascading effects of aircraft arriving late. Examining the
trends in flight delay causes since June 2003 reveals that the largest increase among delay factors
is also late aircraft arriving. This may, in part, be an indicator of possible airline over-scheduling
and/or increased fleet utilization. In recent years, efforts to cut operational cost at airlines have
driven airlines to reduce turn times (i.e., the time aircraft spend parked at the gate being serviced
between flights). These data suggest that either the airlines themselves, the airport infrastructure,





the FAA air traffic management system, or some combination of these aviation system
components cannot fully accommodate this increased operational tempo. The result is cascading
delays as an operational day progresses. This is also evidenced in statistics showing an increase in
delays as it gets later in the operational day (see Figure 3).
Figure 3. System-Wide Percent of Flights Arriving and Departing On Time as a
Function of the Time of Day (2006 Data)
Source: CRS Analysis of Bureau of Transportation Statistics Airline On-Time Performance Data.
It seems somewhat paradoxical that the increased operations tempo can actually contribute to
increased delays. To put this into perspective, it is useful to examine air carrier fleet trends. In

2000, mainline passenger airlines operated 4,488 jets compared to an estimated 3,886 in 2006.


Over the same period, the number of aircraft operated by regional carriers, which are primarily
smaller regional jets, grew from 2,274 in 2000 to an estimated 2,743 in 2006. Taking these two
industry components together, the number of operating passenger aircraft declined from 6,762 in

2000 to an estimated 6,629 in 2006, roughly a 2% decrease. Looking solely at large jets, however,


the trend is much more evident. Large jets in service have declined from 4,462 in 2000 to an





estimated 3,827 in 2006, roughly a 14% decline. Whereas large jets made up about 66% of the
total scheduled passenger service fleet in 2000, today large jets make up about 58%. In terms of
the percentage of jet aircraft in airline operations, large jets made up about 88% of all jets used in
scheduled passenger service in 2000, whereas in 2006, large jets comprised only 68% of all
operating scheduled passenger jets. The trend over the past five years has clearly been toward 8
reducing the number of large jets and increasing the number of smaller regional jets. So, not only
are there fewer aircraft in service compared to 2000, but the aircraft that are being utilized are, on
average, smaller in size and hold fewer passengers. As passenger demand for air travel continues
to grow, these two trends can contribute to increased congestion and the need to sustain increased
operations tempo to handle this growing passenger demand. With an increased operations tempo
and utilization of smaller aircraft, there is greater demand for airport gates, so delays to one
flight—say for weather or maintenance-related issues—can have cascading effects on other
flights because of a lack of gate availability.
The shift toward using smaller aircraft has been a major contributor to the increased traffic at the
three New York metropolitan area airports. For example, a comparison of August 2002 airline
schedules to August 2007 schedules found that, over the past five years, there has been a 128%
increase in the use of aircraft with fewer than 100 seats and an increase of 120% in flights using
aircraft with 100 to 200 seats at JFK. Over that same time period, flights at JFK utilizing aircraft
with more than 200 seats declined by 12%. This illustrates a dramatic shift in the type and scale
of operations at JFK, which has long been regarded as a key origin and destination for
international flight operations with widebody aircraft historically making up a sizable portion of
the flight activity at the airport. The situation has been similar but somewhat less pronounced at
LGA and EWR. Over the past five years, LGA experienced a 49% jump in scheduled flights of
aircraft with fewer than 100 seats, but about a 8% decline in operations using aircraft with more
than 100 seats. At EWR the shift hasn’t been quite as dramatic, but is nonetheless still
considerable. Over the past five years, utilization of aircraft with fewer than 100 seats at EWR
has increased by almost 34%, while there has been relatively little change in the number of flights
using aircraft with more than 100 seats, based on the comparison of August 2002 and August 9

2007 flight schedules.


In addition to this increased operations tempo using smaller aircraft, a variety of other factors
may influence airline scheduling practices, some of which may run counter to initiatives for
reducing congestion and delay. For example, current LGA slot rules impose “use it or lose it”
conditions on the airlines. Airlines have responded by continuing to operate unprofitable flights
rather than concede these coveted slots to their competitors. For example, in June 2007, it was
reported that there were three unprofitable markets, comprising a total of 13 daily flights, 10
operating at LGA. While utilizing large aircraft with high load factors (high percentages of
filled seats) would be best for optimizing limited available capacity at congested airports like
LGA, reviews of airline scheduling practices indicate that continued use of smaller aircraft
operating routes which generate low load factors leads to sub-optimal utilization in scheduling.
Rationales for such strategies among the airlines include offering consumers greater flexibility in

8 See Federal Aviation Administration, FAA Aerospace Forecasts (Fiscal Years 20072020), Washington, DC:
Federal Aviation Administration, Aviation Policy and Plans.
9 David Hughes, “N.Y.’s Delay Donnybrook, Aviation Week & Space Technology, July 30, 2007, pp. 40-42.
10 George L. Donahue, Optimum Fleet Utilization Under Congestion Management at NY LGA, presented at the
Workshop on Allocation and Exchange of Airport Access Rights, The Aspen Institute, Wye River Conference Center,
Queenstown, MD, June 6-8, 2007.





scheduling and serving smaller communities in order to capture or control greater market share at
capacity constrained airports. There are also political considerations and incentives in place to
maintain service to smaller communities, for example through Essential Air Service (EAS)
subsidies. Due to intense competition for market share at high density airports, including the New
York area airports, airlines have no particular incentives to reduce or otherwise modify flight
schedules. While chronic delays and customer dissatisfaction would appear to provide some
impetus for airlines to take action, each airline individually faces a “prisoner’s dilemma,” because
they fear that if they reduce schedules or shift flights to off-peak periods, their competitors could 11
gain an advantage by filling in any schedule openings this might create.
The aviation system in the United States suffers from the fact that flight operations are highly
concentrated at a relatively small number of airports. The 35 busiest airports in the United States
handle about 75 percent of all airline passengers. This is largely because demand for air travel is
highly concentrated within the country’s major metropolitan regions. The New York area, being
the most highly populated metropolitan region, generates a demand for air travel that significantly
strains available capacity. This strain on capacity is not limited to commercial airline travel, as it
also extends to demand for access to airports and airspace by corporate and private jets and
fractionally-owned and chartered aircraft. The major New York area airports, as well as general
aviation reliever airports in the area, have limited options for expansion. An updated
FAA/MITRE Corporation study of capacity needs in the national airspace system released in May 12

2007 concluded that “[a]dditional capacity within the New York Metropolitan Area is needed.”


While this conclusion may now seem obvious even to casual observers, the FAA was slow to
reach this conclusion and the original capacity needs study released in 2004 did not identify the
New York metropolitan area as immediately needing additional capacity.
Many regard Stewart International Airport (SWF), a converted military airbase located about 55
miles north of Manhattan, as potentially providing needed capacity to this region, although the
FAA’s capacity needs study concedes that “it is too early to determine whether [NY/NJ Port 13
Authority acquisition of SWF] will offset the need for additional capacity enhancements.”
Distance from Manhattan and lack of ground transportation infrastructure are two potential
challenges for making effective use of SWF to relieve congestion at the three major New York
area airports, yet many remain hopeful since options to otherwise expand capacity in the region
appear quite limited.
While the focus of current media attention and policy debate has been on congestion and delay in
the New York metropolitan area, this region is not alone in its need for additional airport and
airspace capacity. The FAA/MITRE Corporation 2007 capacity needs study identified 14 airports
and eight metropolitan regions that will need additional capacity beyond that anticipated from 14
ongoing and planned airport expansion projects over the next 17 years. Since further airport

11 Ibid. In game theory, the “prisoner’s dilemma” refers to a competitive game scenario in which players can
collectively gain more by cooperating, but typically compete instead to serve their own self-interests based on their
perception that the other player(s) will also compete rather than cooperate.
12 Federal Aviation Administration and the MITRE Corporation, Capacity Needs in the National Airspace System,
2007-2026, May, 2007, p. 14.
13 Ibid., p. 18.
14 Ibid.





expansion is a limited option, experts are focusing heavily on looking at ways to overcome
technical and procedural constraints on airspace design and utilization in congested areas.
Airspace in congested metropolitan areas is largely constrained by air traffic controller workload
and safety considerations. Emerging technologies to improve the accuracy of aircraft navigation
and surveillance by primarily relying on precision satellite-based navigation capabilities, thereby
allowing more efficient utilization of airspace and greater flexibility in routing flights, are a key
component of the Next Generation Air Transportation System (NGATS) Concept of Operations 15
(CONOPS). However, even if systems development and acquisition is kept on schedule, this
future air traffic control system will not be fully operational for another 17 years. In the
meantime, the FAA has sought to improve the efficiency of the current air traffic system through
airspace redesign initiatives and procedural changes using currently available technologies. For
example, in 2001 the FAA implemented its “National Choke Point Initiative” to reduce airspace
bottlenecks at several points in the Eastern United States, including in the airspace serving the
New York metropolitan airports. This initiative included procedural changes and adding new air
traffic control sectors to better distribute controller workload. It was reported that these initiatives 16
had the effect of reducing delays by 20%. Also, the recently approved NY/NJ/PHL Airspace
Redesign is an initiative to specifically restructure airspace and air traffic flows in the New York
and Philadelphia regions to improve efficiency and reduce delays. According to the FAA, this 17
redesign initiative could also reduce delays by 20%. These initiatives have been combined with
procedural measures, such as ground delays and airspace flow programs as well as the
implementation of various decision-aiding tools to assist in air traffic management. These
approaches are largely regarded as tactical stopgap measures to mitigate delay conditions, but are
not seen by themselves as complete long term solutions for reducing delays as traffic volumes
continue to increase.
Despite some success in reducing delays through these initiatives, traffic growth is having the
effect of offsetting many of the gains achieved by taking these steps to improve system efficiency.
FAA airspace initiatives in the New York area appear to be having a difficult time keeping up
with the growth in demand for air travel in this region. Aviation experts largely agree that a
comprehensive systems-based approach to implementing new technologies and flight procedures
is needed to most effectively address capacity needs and reduce delays across the national
airspace system, particularly in the New York metropolitan region airspace, where chronic delays
are symptomatic of constrained airport and airspace capacity.
The airline industry in particular is advocating for the FAA to take steps to maximize the
utilization of airport and airspace capacity in the New York metropolitan region, arguing that 18
demand-management strategies are, in their opinion, not necessary. The Air Transport
Association (ATA) has specifically called for establishing a New York area air traffic delay
management “czar” to coordinate delay-reduction initiatives, and involving air carriers and other

15 Joint Planning and Development Office, Concept of Operations fo the Next Generation Air Transportation System,
Version 2.0, June 13, 2007.
16 Testimony of Ruth E. Marlin, Executive Vice President, National Air Traffic Controllers Association Before the U.S.
House of Representatives Committee on Transportation & Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Aviation, on the Status of
the Air Traffic Controller Workforce, June 15, 2004.
17 Remarks for Robert A. Sturgell, Acting Administrator, Federal Aviation Administration, Aviation Congestion Relief
Media Briefing, Washington, DC, September 27, 2007.
18 Air Transport Association, Letter to the Honorable Mary Peters, Secretary, U.S. Department of Transportation,
Washington, DC, September 14, 2007.





airspace users in discussions to identify near-term operational and procedural measures to address
system inefficiencies. While the work of the special ARC announced by the DOT would appear to
serve this purpose, it remains unclear what specific solutions this committee may be able to offer
that can improve system efficiency beyond what has already been tried and implemented under
the ongoing NY/NJ/PHL airspace redesign and other airspace and operational initiatives, such as
ground delay and airspace flow management programs that are currently in place. Any further
initiatives not yet implemented may only be able to offer smaller marginal improvements toward
increasing system efficiencies and reducing delays. Therefore, despite opposition from the airline
industry, many academic experts believe that a variety of demand-management or market-based
approaches for addressing congestion and delay at various high-density or capacity constrained
airports, including the three commercial passenger airports serving the New York metropolitan 19
area may need to be considered in the near term.
The role that business jets and other high-performance general aviation aircraft play in air traffic
system congestion and air carrier delays remains both debatable and highly contentious. At busy
air carrier airports, general aviation makes up a relatively small percentage of flight operations.
According to the FAA FY2005 Cost Allocation Report, general aviation aircraft and fractionally-
owned aircraft accounted for less than 4% of all aircraft operations at large hub airports in 20
FY2005. In FY2005, general aviation made up 2.7% of the traffic at LGA, 3.2% of the traffic at 21
EWR, and 2.0% of the traffic at JFK.
The airlines, however, have argued that general aviation operations in terminal airspace and along
the busiest en route corridors place a considerable strain on system capacity, pointing out that the
number of private jet aircraft operating in U.S. airspace has grown from about 1,800 in 1970 to 22
almost 18,000 today. The airlines argue that “[t]he proliferation of these aircraft, in addition to
the unprecedented growth of the business aviation sector, has been the primary factor in the 23
increased workload for FAA.” In the New York area, there is some evidence of the additional
demand for air traffic services from general aviation. At Teterboro Airport (TEB) in Teterboro,
NJ—a major GA reliever for the New York area—total operations counts have remained flat over
the thirty years from 1976 to 2006 (the data actually show a slight decline of 2.3% in total
operations for TEB). Over the same period, however, the number of instrument operations have
increased threefold (306.3% increase in 2006 compared to 1976 levels). Whether and to what
extent this increased general aviation utilization of air traffic services is affecting airline
operations and contributing to delays at nearby airports has not been conclusively determined, but
it remains a specific point of contention among the airlines and general aviation interest groups
such as the National Business Aviation Association (NBAA). Since high-performance general
aviation aircraft typically do not make up a large percentage of the air traffic flying directly to and

19 See NEXTOR: The National Center of Excellence for Aviation Operations, Allocation and Exchange of Airport
Access Rights, Workshop held at the Aspen Institute, Wye River Conference Center, Queenstown, MD, June 6-8, 2007,
available at http://www.isr.umd.edu/airworkshop/.
20 Federal Aviation Administration, FY2005 Cost Allocation Report, January 2007.
21 Federal Aviation Administration, Terminal Area Forecast (TAF), available at http://aspm.faa.gov/main/taf.asp.
22 SeeCorporate Jets Clog Americas Skies,” at http://www.smartskies.org/LearningCenter/atc_users/.
23 Ibid.





from capacity constrained commercial airports, their impact on flight delays could most likely be
addressed through airspace redesign and new technologies and procedures for air traffic
management.


A variety of options for reducing air traffic congestion and minimizing airline delays are under
consideration. While most aviation industry experts believe that the largest gains can be achieved
in the long term through investment in Next Generation Air Transportation System (NGATS or
NextGen) technologies, the current situation is prompting many in government and the aviation
industry to seek out near-term fixes to address congestion and delay, especially in the New York
area. A variety of near-term options are under consideration including phasing-in airspace
redesign plans in the New York/New Jersey/Philadelphia region; opening military airspace to
civilian flights under certain conditions; implementing ground delay programs, airspace flow
control programs, and other congestion management tools to improve the flow of air traffic;
phasing-in technology and procedural changes to reduce aircraft separation and improve airspace
utilization; and possibly improving airline schedule optimization at high density airports by
utilizing larger aircraft, a practice known in the industry as upgauging.
As mentioned earlier, the FAA recently finalized its plans for redesigning airspace in the New
York, New Jersey, and Philadelphia areas (the NY/NJ/PHL Airspace Redesign). In the near future,
the FAA will begin implementing this plan which is touted to more efficiently use airspace and
runways at the New York area airports and at Philadelphia International Airport (PHL). The plan
includes greater use of fanned departure headings and parallel arrivals, as well as greater
flexibility in traffic flows to handle severe weather conditions. The FAA anticipates that
implementation of the NY/NJ/PHL Airspace Redesign will cut delays by a cumulative total of

200,000 hours annually, resulting in a savings of $248 million annually in airline operating costs, 24


plus another $37 million annually because of the increased flexibility during severe weather.
These redesign initiatives probably offer the greatest near-term potential for reducing delays at
the New York area airports without curtailing or otherwise modifying airline schedules.
Currently, the FAA negotiates in real-time with the DOD to open up airspace to civilian traffic on 25
an as-needed basis, such as to detour flights around thunderstorms. However, prior to the 2007
Thanksgiving holiday travel period, President Bush announced a plan to open military airspace
along the east coast to airline flights during a five day period from the day before Thanksgiving
through the Sunday after Thanksgiving. During this time, the FAA established two additional east

24 Statement of Robert A. Sturgell, Acting Administrator, Testimony Before the House Committee on Transportation
and Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Aviation, On Airline Delays and Consumer Issues, September 26, 2007.
25 Madhu Unnikrishnan, “DOT: Military Airspace Opened For Thanksgiving.” Aviation Daily, November 16, 2007.





coast flight paths, dubbed the “Thanksgiving express lane” by Administration officials.26 This
prearranged opening of military airspace over the entire Thanksgiving weekend was touted by 27
some as an “unprecedented step” while dismissed by others as giving “[air traffic] controllers a 28
power they already have and have used for years,” namely the authority to utilize military
airspace during holiday periods when the military is typically not training. The Air Transport
Association (ATA) described the utilization of military airspace over this period as being
moderate, ranging between 10 to 40 aircraft per hour being routed along these temporary flight 29
paths. Whether the use of this airspace helped reduce or mitigate delays is hard to say,
particularly at the New York area airports where delays over the 2007 Thanksgiving holiday were
largely attributed to low ceilings and reduced visibility which impacted arrival and departure
spacing. In the past, use of military airspace has been on more of a case-by-case basis, such as to
reroute traffic around weather, leading some to consider whether more extensive use of military
airspace along the east coast could be a possible fix for airspace congestion and resulting delays.
Experts have mixed opinions regarding the degree to which more extensive use of military
airspace can relieve airspace congestion and mitigate delays, especially if military airspace is
opened only for sporadic, temporary intervals. This is because the FAA’s airway structure and
arrival and departure routes along the east coast have been designed in coordination with the
DOD taking into consideration those areas carved out for military use. Turning on and off civilian
flight activity through these areas would require continued close coordination between the FAA
and the DOD, and this is not something that the relatively rigid current airspace structure and
procedures were specifically designed for. Military airspace, however, is often inactive (that is,
not utilized for any military purpose), thus offering potential options for more direct routing of
civilian flights and additional flight paths to alleviate airspace congestion. The difficulty is
knowing when military airspace will be inactive and could be made available for civilian use.
Better coordination of airspace scheduling between the DOD and the FAA could potentially open
additional routes and give air traffic controllers greater flexibility in routing flights during certain
periods of the day, particularly as more and more aircraft are allowed to utilize direct routing
capabilities relying on satellite-based navigation and are thus not as dependent on the rigid legacy
airway structure. Nonetheless, most concede that the overall impact of such actions would likely
be relatively small, although perhaps not insignificant, because they do not address the primary
issue of airport capacity constraints at the busiest airports along the east coast.
A variety of decision aiding tools to help airspace managers and air traffic controllers better
optimize the utilization of airspace and minimize the disruption caused by significant weather and
other events have been developed and are being continually refined. One approach has been to
implement ground delays at origin airports for specific destination airports, like LGA, to better
meter the flow of arrivals, thereby reducing arrival delays and the additional congestion of

26 Holly Rosenkrantz and John Hughes, “Bush to Open More Airspace to Cut Holiday Trip Delays,” Bloomberg,
November 15, 2007.
27 Ibid.
28 James Fallows, “Thankfulness is Great, But What Is the NYT Thinking?, The Atlantic.com, November 22, 2007.
29 Air Transport Association, ATA 2007 Thanksgiving Holiday Operational Earlier Updates, November 17-27, 2007,
Washington, DC: Air Transport Association.





already crowded airspace that this may cause. In addition, airspace flow programs (AFPs) have
been used to limit congestion in specific airspace sectors. Ground delays and AFPs can also be
imposed on general aviation aircraft to limit their disruption of traffic flows to and from major
airports that could trigger delays. Other decision-aiding tools that the FAA has developed for
improving efficient utilization of airspace include the flight schedule monitor (FSM), for
managing ground delays and airspace flow implementation, and the flight schedule analyzer
(FSA), used to assess the effectiveness of ground delay and airspace flow procedures thereby
allowing incremental improvements. Also the traffic management advisor (TMA) aids controllers
in optimizing arrival sequences into major airports, and an adaptive compression program can aid 30
in identifying controllers and reallocating slots that might otherwise go unused. The FAA has
also relied on collaborative decision making tools and operational “playbooks” for minimizing
disruptions and delays caused by severe weather and other factors. Improving upon these various
operational tools and techniques for optimizing air traffic flows and airspace utilization is an
ongoing FAA initiative. However, there is concern that without accompanying technological
advances in navigation and surveillance capabilities, these efforts will yield diminishing marginal
improvements in delay reduction.
Airport traffic is constrained or “metered” at several points in the aviation system. On the airport
itself, aircraft are constrained by the number of available gates, and arrivals and departures are
metered by runway occupancy and arrival and departure spacing requirements. In the air, specific
entry and exit points into and out of terminal airspace, referred to as gates, also constrict traffic
flows in congested areas, and aircraft separation requirements impose limits on air traffic density.
Technology to improve navigation and surveillance accuracy is seen as a long-term solution to
safely increase traffic density and increase the flexibility of airspace utilization in congested
terminal airspace and along busy routes. While the FAA has offered that the Next Generation Air
Transportation System (NGATS or NextGen) provides a great hope for alleviating airspace
capacity constraints and system delays, even if the system development stays on schedule, it will
not, as mentioned earlier, be fully implemented for another 17 years.
By exploiting the improved navigational precision of aircraft satellite-based navigation systems
using required navigation performance (RNP) and area navigation (RNAV) procedures, the FAA
and airline operators can achieve better utilization of airspace, thereby increasing system capacity
and potentially reducing delays. Examples include increased numbers of fanned departure
headings to increase airspace utilization for departures, more closely spaced approaches to
parallel runways, increased use of direct routing capabilities, and greater flexibility for routing
aircraft around weather systems. These capabilities demonstrate how emerging satellite-based
technologies have the potential to create opportunities for procedural changes that can
significantly improve system efficiency, thereby potentially reducing delays. At the New York
area airports and at PHL, RNAV/RNP arrivals and departures have recently been made available
on a limited basis, and it is anticipated that they will be utilized to a much greater extent as
implementation of the NY/NJ/PHL Airspace Redesign progresses.

30 Statement of Robert A. Sturgell, Acting Administrator, Testimony Before the House Committee on Transportation
and Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Aviation, On Airline Delays and Consumer Issues, September 26, 2007.





Another option for reducing congestion is to provide service using smaller numbers of larger
aircraft. The selection of larger aircraft is referred to in the airline industry as upgauging. By
upgauging aircraft in combination with schedule reductions, airlines could serve the same number
of passengers with fewer flights. The airline trend in recent years, however, has been to
“downgauge” rather than upgauge. This has been a particularly prevalent trend over the past five
years as airlines have sought ways to increase load factor (the ratio of seats filled with revenue
paying customers to total available seats) and reduce operating costs in a highly competitive
market. At airports where there is significant competition, airlines have also sought to provide
customers with the greatest amount of scheduling flexibility, offering more frequent flights,
typically on smaller aircraft to keep load factors high and operations profitable. Without any
particular incentives for upgauging, airlines are likely to be reluctant to do so on their own accord
for fear that, by offering fewer flights to customers, they would be put at a competitive
disadvantage. Airlines are also faced with the task of optimizing fleet composition in a manner
that serves a broad array of markets in the most cost effective manner. So, while upgauging
aircraft to serve highly competitive markets may help alleviate congestion and delay problems at
specific airports, these larger aircraft may not be the best options for a particular airline’s overall
route structure. Determining an airlines optimum fleet mix is a complex task for airlines that
serve a wide variety of markets, so simply upgauging aircraft serving capacity constrained
airports may not necessarily be in the best interests of the airlines.


Demand management is a somewhat broad term that suggests that capacity, hence congestion, can
be controlled using administrative or economic mechanisms, or a combination of the two.
Historically, aviation usage of the term demand management is associated with airport slot
controls and the allocation of slots. Over the last 4 decades slot controls have been imposed using
both administrative and economic measures at 4 airports in the United States. During this period,
as will be discussed below, there were attempts to create a market for slots, but these markets
have never lived up to the expectations of their proponents.
Congestion pricing, the focus of several policy statements by Secretary of Transportation Mary
Peters, can be viewed as a form of demand management that tries to use pricing techniques to 31
effect desired results in reducing congestion. Congestion pricing can be imposed at the airport
level, for example, as part of, or as an adjunct to, landing fees. As will be discussed, there is some
limited experience with the use of these mechanisms in the United States and in the United
Kingdom (UK). Congestion pricing could also be applied to air traffic control (ATC) activities,
though to date this mechanism has not been specifically applied in the United States or elsewhere.
The use of demand management techniques to ration finite amounts of transportation
infrastructure has long been supported by economists. Americans, however, appear to have an
aversion to tolls and the other transportation pricing mechanisms that are the stock and trade of
demand management practice. Roads in this nation, for example, are provided largely as free

31White House Confirms Airline Scheduling Meetings for JFK.” Aviation Daily. September 28, 2007. p. 1.





goods, especially in the minds of drivers who believe they pay for roads sufficiently through taxes
at the gas pump. This same framework also exists in the aviation world, with the airline ticket tax
and associated taxes serving as a proxy for the highway fuels tax. Broadly based taxes, such as
fuel taxes, however, are viewed by economists as proxies for user fees rather than as true user
fees. As a result, taxes are generally seen as a relatively poor mechanism for pricing
infrastructure. Nonetheless some observers, find it rather remarkable that a nation that
differentiates access to many of its infrastructure systems on a price basis, e.g.
telecommunications peak period pricing, has no comparable mechanism that differentiates for use
of the national aviation system.
Congestion pricing is normally opposed by many groups in the aviation community. Historically,
the groups most vociferous in their objections to this mechanism are regional airlines, business
aircraft operators, and general aviation aircraft operators. All of these groups believe that
congestion pricing could be used to discriminate against them and will have the effect of
reserving what are publicly supplied assets—airports and ATC—for large airlines. It should be
pointed out that the airline industry has also objected to certain demand management proposals 32
and is objecting to the imposition of congestion pricing at JFK. Residents of small and medium
sized communities, primarily served by regional airlines, are also concerned that congestion
pricing will price them out of major airports and further limit their access to the national aviation
system.
Well publicized capacity and delay problems in the late 1960s played an important role in the
congressional debates that led to passage of the Airport and Airway Development and Revenue
Acts of 1970 (P.L. 91-258, 1970 Act). The 1970 Act is seen as a milestone in that it created a
programmatic framework for the modernization of the National ATC and airport systems, and
provided a funding mechanism to pay for many of the needed upgrades—the airport and airway
trust fund.
By the end of the 1960s, stories about delays at major airports were a staple of the evening
television news and front page articles in major newspapers. Beginning in 1968 the FAA chose to
intervene by instituting capacity controls at four airports: Chicago O’Hare (ORD); New York 33
Kennedy (JFK); New York LaGuardia (LGA); and Washington Reagan National (DCA). The
high density rule (HDR), as it was known, instituted controls by allocating slots (takeoffs or
landings) amongst the incumbent airlines serving each airport. When the slot controls were
implemented there was some hope that they could be removed at some not too distant point in
time. Instead, the controls would last for over 3 decades. The slot controls system, which was
modified on several occasions over the years, probably did constrain excessive growth in 34
congestion at the 4 airports, but it did not eliminate it.
From 1968 until 1986 the allocation of slots was primarily handled by a scheduling committee at
each airport made up largely by representatives of the incumbent airlines. The scheduling

32 Schofield, Adrian.Debate Over JFK Delays Sparks Talk of Congestion Pricing. Aviation Week. October 29, 2007.
33 Newark Airport was briefly subject to FAA slot controls as well.
34 For a more detailed description of the history and origin of slot controls, see Gleimer, Eileen M. “Slot Regulation At
High Density Airports: How Did We Get Here And Where Are We Going? Journal of Air Law and Commerce. V. 61.
May -June 1996. p. 877-931.





committees essentially allocated slots amongst themselves on a voluntary basis. This somewhat
cozy arrangement was viewed by many as a major restraint on competition. Not surprisingly the
scheduling committees failed to provide many slots to the “new entrant” airlines being created in
the wake of airline deregulation in 1978. To the extent that new entrants did get slot awards they
were provided through intervention by the FAA.
In 1986 an attempt was made to use market forces to open up some of the slots at the airports.
This so called “buy/sell” rule allowed incumbent airlines the right to buy or sell slots in a
secondary market. To insure that incumbent airlines actually gave up their slots the FAA
established minimum use rule for slots. If the slot was not used over a period of time the airline
was supposed to lose control over it and return it to the FAA. In reality the system proved far less 35
useful than hoped. Incumbent airlines proved largely unwilling to give up what they regarded as
a controlled asset, especially to would-be competitors. Sales of slots, did occur, sometimes as a
result of an airline merger, restructuring, etc., but largely in a way that led to even greater control 36
of the HDR airports by major airlines.
By the end of the 1990s it was clear that slot markets had not worked as hoped. FAA intervention
over the slot control period, mostly through the award of exemption authority for certain airlines
to provide certain types of services, also was seen as having only limited positive impact on
competition at the HDR airports. In the end, it was this concern about a lack of competition that
led Congress to legislate a phase out of slot controls at all but Washington Reagan National, as st
part of the Wendell H. Ford Aviation Investment and Reform Act for the 21 Century (AIR-21,
P.L. 106-181).
AIR-21 called for a all slot controls to be eliminated at Chicago O’Hare by July 2002, and
controls at New York airports were to end January 1, 2007. The law also provided certain
exemptions from these deadlines for certain types of aircraft. The first consequences of this phase
out occurred at LaGuardia in 2000 when airlines took advantage of small regional jet exemptions
provided for in AIR-21 and rapidly initiated a large number of new flights to and from the airport.
This jump in regional jet traffic was somewhat unexpected and the FAA was forced to impose a th
moratorium on new service in September 2000. The events of September 11 temporarily
alleviated what was then viewed as a growing problem, but the problem returned and capacity
controls were reintroduced by the FAA.
At Chicago O’Hare, the FAA has been able to manage capacity since slot controls were
eliminated only by seeking voluntary reductions in scheduled traffic from the incumbent airlines,
primarily American and United. In late summer 2006, the FAA adopted a rule that limits
operations at the airport until new airport capacity becomes available, which is expected to occur
in 2009.
Unlike LaGuardia and O’Hare, JFK did not see the same rapid growth in traffic after passage of
AIR-21. For part of this period this was a result of decreases in overall traffic after September 11,
2001. In the last couple of years, however, there has been a major increase in traffic at JFK to the
point that the FAA is now seeking to implement some sort of capacity controls at the airport.

35 Berardino, Frank. “History of the Slot Exchange Market in the US and Some Implications. Presentation at Nextor
Workshop on Allocation and Exchange of Airport Access Rights. June 6, 2007. http://nextor.org/Conferences/
200706_Airport_Access_Rights/Berardino.pdf.
36 Ibid. p. 10.





Options being explored include voluntary rescheduling actions on the part of the airlines or
implementation of peak period and/or congestion pricing.
At the time of this writing the FAA seems intent on limiting JFK flights on a per hour basis.37 The
FAA will attempt to meet this goal by asking individual airlines to limit their service at the airport
accordingly, but apparently will not allow the airlines to meet to discuss flight scheduling en
mass. Longer term, however, the FAA still seems to be focused on creating a congestion pricing 38
scheme to allocate capacity at the airport.
On a few occasions over the last three decades, the now sunset Civil Aeronautics Board and later
the DOT gave airlines limited antitrust immunity in order to discuss and coordinate schedules.
Each of these grants was temporary in nature and related to specific events in the aviation
industry, such as the aftereffects of the 1981 air traffic controllers strike. In early 2001, after the
aviation system experienced massive delays in 2000, Congress was considering legislation (H.R.
1407 and S. 633) that would have allowed airlines to ask the Secretary of Transportation for
authority to discuss schedules when scheduled traffic exceeded airport capacity and gave the
Secretary the authority to approve the resulting agreements. The authors of these bills viewed the
provisions as a short term solution to existing capacity problems, which they hoped would be
alleviated over time by the creation of new airport and ATC capacity. The events of September 11,
however, would abrogate the need for this legislation at that time.
Early in 2007 concern about congestion at LGA and other airports caused the Bush
Administration and the House Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure to include
provisions in FAA reauthorization legislation under consideration at that time, H.R. 1356/S. 1076
and H.R. 2881, respectively, to deal with this issue. The Bush Administration approach seeks to
study congestion pricing, which will be discussed subsequently. H.R. 2881, however, contains a
provision which implies a process that seems similar in some respects to a limited grant of
antitrust immunity. In Section 422, the FAA Administrator is given the authority to seek a
voluntary meeting of air carriers at a congested airport for the purposes of schedule reduction. If
this meeting is unsuccessful, the Administrator is given the authority to facilitate schedule
reduction as he/she sees fit.
A similar conversation has now begun in conjunction with the JFK situation. Several parties have
called on the FAA to be more active in schedule coordination. For the moment, the FAA has not
sought antitrust immunity and is meeting with air carriers one at a time in an attempt to reduce 39
flights into the airport next year. Should this effort fail to achieve its desired results, it is quite
possible that the various parties to the scheduling debate might ask for a process that includes at
least some form of antitrust immunity. In 2001, there was considerable concern from some
observers that antitrust-created scheduling committees or mechanisms would be unable to avoid
competitive issues that might lead to industry collusion on items such as service and fares. There
also were concerns that scheduling committees, like those used at HDR airports, might become a
semi-permanent and anti-competitive feature of the industry.

37FAA Looks to Cap JFK Flights at 80-81 Per Hour.” Aviation Daily. October 22, 2007. p. 2.
38 Ibid.
39FAA Begins JFK Scheduling Talks, But Airlines Slam Flight Cuts.” Aviation Daily. October 24, 2007. p. 1.





In concept the idea of congestion pricing is quite simple, for example, it may consist of modified
landing and/or air navigation fees to change behavior in a way that uses the market to allocate
available infrastructure. It is the application of the concept in the aviation sector that has proved
difficult. To a large extent the difficulty arises because airport runways and air navigation (ATC)
services within the United States are normally provided by the public sector and are regarded as
public goods. Compounding this problem is the fact that airports are usually local and/or regional
monopolies, while ATC services are provided by a national monopoly (such as the FAA in the
U.S. context). Pricing in the public sector is, therefore, not focused on creating a profit as it would
be for a private firm, but rather on providing for cost recovery or some other publically
determined goal. Hence, the forces that routinely set prices in a competitive marketplace are
largely absent.
The concept of congestion pricing predates the invention of the airplane. Tolling, which in certain
instances is a form of congestion pricing, has been around for centuries. Over the last several
decades there has been considerable research on the usefulness and application of congestion
pricing mechanisms to transportation infrastructure worldwide. Most of this research, however,
has focused on surface transportation. In the surface transportation world, there is a large and
growing body of academic literature on the subject. The similar conversation in the aviation
world is much more limited in scope, with research on the subject being done by a comparatively
small number of individuals and groups. And, in fact, several of the authors of studies on aviation
pricing are doing so based, at least in part, on their research on surface transportation pricing
issues.
The Bush Administration, and especially Secretary of Transportation Peters, favor market 40
mechanisms for infrastructure development and maintenance in all transportation modes. It was,
therefore, not a surprise that the Administration made a review of congestion pricing part of its
proposal for FAA reauthorization in early 2007, H.R. 1356/S. 1076. The FAA proposal seeks to
establish a pilot program to evaluate market-based mechanisms to relieve congestion at up to 16
airports (including LGA, which was the subject of a separate provision). The FAA proposal was
not adopted in either the House (H.R. 2881) or Senate (S. 1300) reauthorization bills still under
consideration at the end of 2007.
Airports in the United States currently charge landing fees based on aircraft weight. These are
generally fixed and do not vary over the time of day. With a couple of small exceptions, there is
no correlation between the landing fee and congestion, although there may be some correlation
between fee levels and infrastructure needs at the airport. Typically, in the absence of specific
infrastructure needs, airport landing fees are determined on the basis of the
historical/administrative costs associated with the airport’s provision of service to the airlines and
its own operating cost requirements. While landing fees are an important source of revenue for
most airports, they are not the only source. And at many airports landing fees are not even the
majority source of airport income. At very large airports, for example, the airport may receive far

40Transportation Congestion Pricing Would Ease Problems at Airports, on Highways, Peters Tells Panel.” Daily
Report for Executives. BNA, Inc. No. 202. October 19, 2007. p. A-9.





more income from concession fees than it does from landing fees and other airside related
activities.
Congestion pricing is an idea that has not yet come to fruition in the aviation world for a variety
of reasons, some of which will be discussed below. As a result, the body of experience with
congestion pricing is quite limited, having been applied in some form only at New York’s and
Boston’s major air carrier airports, and at London Heathrow (LHR) airport in the United
Kingdom (UK). In no case can the application of these fees be viewed as having been entirely
successful from the perspective of congestion pricing theory. And in no case can any of these
examples be viewed as having created a system that would meet the theoretical definition of true 41
congestion pricing. Each of these experiences is discussed briefly below.
In 1968, the Port Authority of New York and New Jersey (Port Authority) instituted a $25
fee/surcharge on all aircraft operations for aircraft with 25 seats or less during peak hours at the 42
three air carrier airports it operated. The specific intent of this first known instance of peak
period pricing in the United States was to reduce GA operations at the three airports. The hope
was that GA operations, especially those using LGA, would move to Teterboro Airport (TEB),
which was also operated by the Port Authority and had no scheduled air service. No additional
fees were to be imposed on GA aircraft that chose to use TEB as a substitute. Not coincidentally,
this action took place during the same time period that saw the implementation of the HDR slot
controls discussed earlier.
GA interests attempted to overturn these surcharges in the federal courts but were ultimately 43
unsuccessful in doing so. The Court found that the intent of the surcharge was reasonable and
that the Port Authority had not discriminated against GA. In part, this was because the Court held
that TEB provided a reasonable alternative for GA aircraft that wished to avoid the surcharge. The
peak period surcharge system at LGA remains in place today.
The peak period pricing system using landing fee surcharges was successful in moving the
majority of GA traffic out of LGA and into TEB. In this respect, the Port Authority experience
can be viewed as having been successful. It should, however, be recognized that the goals of the
surcharge were modest when compared to the peak period pricing regimes promoted by economic
theorists. Hence, it would be difficult to draw on this experience as a guide to how peak period
surcharges might affect the movement of airline traffic in the context of the ongoing FAA/DOT
slot allocation investigation at JFK.

41 For more detailed information on each example see Schank, Joshua L. “Solving airside airport congestion: Why peak
runway pricing is not working. Journal of Air Transport Management. Vol. 11. Elsevier Ltd. 2005. p. 417-425.
42 Exemptions were provided for air taxis at JFK and EWR.
43 Schank. p. 420.





Some would argue that Boston Logan’s 1988 attempt at using pricing to modify airport traffic
flow was not, in fact, an example of congestion pricing, per se. The Program for Airfield Capacity
Efficiency (PACE) changed the landing fee structure at the airport by moving away from a strictly
weight-based fee and instead creating a base fee unrelated to weight for all aircraft landings with
an additional weight-based fee. The net effect of this system was to significantly raise the landing
fees paid by GA aircraft and smaller commuter/regional airline aircraft as compared to those now
paid by larger airline operated aircraft. Massport, the state agency operating the airport, believed
that this pricing system would reduce congestion by providing an incentive for airlines to
schedule fewer flights during the day using larger aircraft and cause GA and other aircraft to fly
to other Boston area airports. In short, Massport was attempting to use landing fees as an
upguaging strategy.
GA and the commuter/regional airlines faced with higher fees mounted a legal challenge to the
PACE program. The complicated legal battle that ensued is discussed in more detail later in this
report. For the purposes of this discussion only the result of that process is addressed. The final
decision in the case was made by an Administrative Law Judge (ALJ) at DOT who decided that
the PACE program discriminated against GA and commuter/regional airlines for several 44
reasons. Important among these was the lack of an acceptable alternative airport for the users
being charged the higher fees. Interestingly, however, the ALJ specifically protected the right of
the airport to adopt a landing fee system different from the weight based system in place at a later
date.
There is nothing inherently sacrosanct about weight-based fees, and nothing in the law that 45
precludes Massport from changing its method of cost allocation.
As a result of the court action, the PACE program was only in place for six months and it is not
clear that the reduction in flights during that period can be specifically attributed to the PACE 46
program. In the intervening years Massport has adopted, but not implemented, a peak period
surcharge methodology that it believes complies with DOT’s requirements. The surcharge itself
will only be implemented when traffic delays reach predetermined levels.
London Heathrow (LHR) is one of the world’s most congested airports. In an attempt to modify
traffic flows it has imposed a peak period pricing regime since 1972. At that time the airport
created a new landing fee structure that included flight length, passenger load, time-of-day and
weight-based elements. The fees also were related to the individual airline’s ability to pay the fee.
Over time the specific elements of the LHR fee structure have evolved. For example, after
numerous protests by international carriers the distance related portion of the fee was eliminated
in 1978. To the chagrin of all air carriers at LHR the British Airports Authority (BAA) which
operated the airport responded by dramatically raising the fixed element of the fee so that many
air carriers actually ended up paying higher fees than they had previously.

44 Leo, Flavio. “Boston Logan International Airport’s Peak Period Surcharge Regulation-Overview.” Power Point
Presentation. June 6-8, 2007. Can be found at http://nextor.org/Conferences/200706_Airport_Access_Rights/Leo.pdf.
45 Ibid.
46 Ibid.





BAA was a public entity in the 1970s when the peak period fees were implemented. Since 1987 it
has been a private firm. In the late 1980s, U.S. air carriers upset over the complicated and high
landing fees at LHR, successfully sought international arbitration over the fees. The findings of
that process concurred with the U.S. air carrier view and BAA was required to reach a financial 47
settlement with the carriers. Irrespective of the U.S. air carrier experience, other elements of the
landing fee structure have continued to change, but the single constant over time has been a
consistent increase in the landing fees.
LHR is a heavily congested slot controlled airport with much of the capacity (slots) at the airport
reserved as a result of international aviation agreements. Therefore, there are other mechanisms in
place at the airport besides peak period pricing that allocate capacity to some degree. Airline
access to LHR is one of the most sought after commodities in the world of aviation. It is,
therefore, an airport that nearly all international airlines regard as a desirable destination,
regardless of the high landing fees and other costs associated with its use. Not surprisingly, major
airlines have continued to seek additional service opportunities at the airport. This has not been
the case for commuter/regional airline service that has largely moved to alternative London 48
airports such as Stansted.
Most observers would suggest that the London example is the closest to true congestion pricing
and has had some of the types of results that one might theoretically expect from its application.
The reality, however, is that LHR’s peak period fees have never really created a market-based
allocation of traffic amongst major airlines. This is due primarily to the desirability of LHR as a
destination. Regardless of the high fees at the airport, airlines appear to have been able to transfer
all of the costs associated with the peak period pricing regime to their passengers through higher
fares. Interestingly, congestion is such at LHR that there is no longer a true peak period and the
landing fees have been modified to recognize this reality.
There are a number of issues that will need to be considered as part of any consideration of
congestion pricing. Each of these issues is potentially contentious. What follows is a brief
discussion of several of these issues.
Although there are other airport related charges that might be modified or created to effect
congestion pricing at an airport, experience to date clearly shows a preference for using landing
fees as the principal mechanism for price setting. In the United States, the setting of landing fees
has been the domain of the airport operator. The legal discussion that follows this section will
show that landing fees can be challenged on various grounds, but nonetheless airports have wide
discretion in setting these fees so long as they do not discriminate against specific users and the
methodology employed in setting the fees is considered fair. As a result, airport operators might
contend and have, in the past, argued that they should determine the pricing policy to be used.
Airport proponents might also argue that they can also effect the rationing of airport capacity by
imposing fees on other types of airport airside infrastructure such as terminal gates.

47 Schank. p. 423.
48 Ibid.





Although most of the discussion to date about congestion pricing has been focused on the use of a
specific airport, or groups of airports, it is possible to consider congestion pricing of the airspace
in the proximity of the airport or region as an alternate pricing mechanism. In this instance a user
fee might be set by the FAA for access to an airport’s related airspace. TRACON (terminal radar
approach control)-related user fees were part of the FAA’s 2007 reauthorization proposal (H.R.
1356/S. 1076). These proposed fees were not seen as congestion pricing fees, however, but rather
as a cost recovery mechanism.
Two important issues that will be raised in any congestion pricing environment are the related
questions of what kinds of outcomes the fees are to achieve and how any money collected is to be
used. If the goal is true congestion relief the fees might have to be set quite high in order to
prompt airlines to make schedule changes. One possible result of high fees, however, is that
certain user groups such as regional airlines providing Essential Air Service (EAS) or other
services to smaller communities might be priced out of specific markets. This result, and other
similar types of exclusions, could be at odds with the existing public policy goal of providing
broad access to the national aviation system.
How collected fees might be used also has potential implications that could determine whether or
not congestion fees would enjoy public and/or airline industry acceptance. For example, the use
of landing fees to fund the operating costs of an airport and to pay for the creation of airport
infrastructure is broadly accepted as an appropriate use for these funds. This might not be the case
if fees were instead designated for U.S. Treasury General Funds without any specific designation 49
for aviation purposes.
Also in question is how congestion fees might affect airline fares at an individual airport. Airlines
ultimately transfer their costs to their passengers. It is well understood that airline fares to and
from airports where a single air carrier dominates the market are higher than they are at airports
with high levels of competition. Congestion fees could result in greater concentration at certain
airports giving air carriers with the majority of service at an airport significant new market
pricing power. Unknown is whether congestion fees could result in high airline fares leading to
public unhappiness with the resultant capacity rationing system. This especially would be the case
in markets where substitute airports and/or other transportation alternatives were lacking. On the
other hand, if high fees did result in significant reductions in air carrier delay and improved flight
reliability, the public might accept the higher fares.
Since the HDR process was first implemented there have been numerous attempts to create
market forces for their allocation. As discussed earlier, most of these attempts were seen as not
having fully served their intended purposes. Some researchers, however, have suggested that
these airport-centric mechanisms have not embraced the market sufficiently and that slot-related
charges are still a viable option for the allocation of airport and airspace capacity.

49 For a further discussion of some of the issues associated with this issue, see Plavin, Z. David. “Using the Revenues
from Airport Pricing. Policy Brief No. 68. The Reason Foundation. November 2007. 12 p.





An approach suggested by some researchers is the slot auction. In one instance the researchers
suggest a multi-level auction process to allocate capacity at congested airports using long-term
leases of slots at congested airports (one year or so), with a secondary market that allows airlines
to trade these leases, and an additional market that allows airlines to trade these resources 50
amongst themselves on a day-to-day basis. In this particular instance the market would likely be
run by the FAA with funds derived from the slot auctions reserved for airspace infrastructure
improvements. The researchers recognize a significant number of issues that might arise from this 51
process, but believe it could be a useful mechanism for the allocation of capacity.

The consideration and potential imposition of congestion pricing or other related mechanisms at
airports raises numerous legal issues and highlights a long-standing tension in aviation law
between federal uniformity and supremacy over airspace and air safety concerns on the one hand,
and local control over airports and ground facilities on the other. This tension, in addition to legal
issues related to the ability of airports to use congestion pricing or similar mechanisms in
conjunction with the federal financial support received through programs such as the Airport
Improvement Program (AIP), may have a significant impact on the type of mechanism suggested
and considered.
As noted earlier, it appears that the legal issues related to congestion pricing mechanisms have
been primarily identified by the two local airport authorities, who sought to impose such systems
over the legal objections, generally on preemption grounds, of the FAA and other adversely
affected parties. To date, the FAA has not suggested the imposition of a federal congestion pricing
mechanism on local airports. As a result, it is unclear precisely what, if any, legal issues may arise
should the situation reverse itself and congestion pricing become a federal mandate as opposed to
a local solution seeking federal approval.
This section of the report will proceed as follows. First, it will review and survey the current laws
that govern airports, including the federal preemption statute as well as several other federal laws
that constrain what local airports are permitted to do with fees charged and money granted by
federal programs such as the AIP. Second, the report will discuss current law as it relates to
airport’s proprietary powers. In other words, given the federal statutory structure, what authority,
if any, is left to the local governments and airport authorities with respect to implementing
congestion pricing mechanisms? Third, the report will review the two previous examples of
alternative pricing mechanisms proposed by local airport authorities, both of which resulted in
federal litigation. The first, in 1969, at New York’s LaGuardia Airport, was approved by the
federal court, while the second, at Boston’s Logan Airport, was rejected by the reviewing court.
Finally, this section will discuss some of the legal issues that may arise should the FAA attempt to
offer congestion pricing as a federal mandate. These may include such issues as whether the FAA
has the proper statutory authority and whether laws related to the financing and use of funds by
airports may need to be adjusted or amended.

50 Ball, Michael, Donohue, George, and Hoffman, Karla. Auctions for the Safe, Efficient and Equitable Allocation of
Airspace System Resources. Found in Cramton, P., Y. Shoham and R. Steinberg, eds. Combined Auctions, MIT Press,
Cambridge, Chapter 22, p 507-538. 2006.
51 Ibid.





Since the passage of the Civil Aeronautics Act in 1938 (CAA),52 the federal government has
worked to establish a coherent national aviation policy that places the primary responsibility for
regulating the air transportation system with federal agencies, while at the same time attempting
to retain local control over certain ground-related elements, including monitoring of noise, land-
use, and zoning. The CAA set forth, inter alia, the encouragement and development of the air
transportation system, the regulation of air transportation to assure a high degree of safety and
sound economic conditions, and the promotion of efficient service by air carriers without unfair 53
competitive practices or unjust discrimination. Although replaced in 1958 by the Federal 54
Aviation Act, the general policy language has largely been retained and the federal government
has continued to assert primary control over much of the aviation sector, especially with respect
to airspace, safety, and discrimination related issues. In addition, the Federal Aviation Act
included a specific preemption provision that prohibits state and local authorities, including 55
airport authorities, from enacting and enforcing laws related to airline “price, route, or service.”
Moreover, the statutory language expressly preserves state and local authority with respect to an 56
airport’s “proprietary powers,” which will be discussed in more detail below. Finally, it should
be noted that most economic regulation of the aviation sector was eliminated by the adoption of 57
the Airline Deregulation Act of 1978.
With respect to airspace, current law clearly establishes that it is the federal government that 58
controls the sovereignty of U.S. airspace. Specifically, the Federal Aviation Administration
(FAA) is charged with “develop[ing] plans and policy for the use of the navigable airspace and
assign[ing] by regulation or order the use of the airspace necessary to ensure the safety of aircraft 59
and the efficient use of airspace.” Statutes such as these are generally considered “field
preemption” statutes or instances where Congress, by the nature of its action, can claim to have
preempted or occupied an entire area of the law. Generally, the Supreme Court has found field
preemption in two types of situations: (1) where “the scheme of federal regulation is sufficiently
comprehensive to make reasonable the inference that Congress ‘left no room’ for supplementary 60
state regulation;” or (2) “where the field is one in which ‘the federal interest is so dominant that 61
the federal system will be assumed to preclude enforcement of state laws on the same subject.’”
As a result of these statutes, the states and other political subdivisions such as local governments

52 Civil Aeronautics Act of 1938, P.L. 75-706, 52 Stat. 973 (1938).
53 See id.
54 Federal Aviation Act of 1958, P.L. 85-726, 72 Stat. 731 (1958).
55 Id. at § 105 (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. § 41713(b)(1) (2000)).
56 49 U.S.C. § 41713(b)(3) (2000).
57 Airline Deregulation Act of 1978, P.L. 95-504, 92 Stat 1705 (1978).
58 See id. at § 307 (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. § 40103(a)(1) (2000) (stating that[t]he United States
Government has exclusive sovereignty of airspace of the United States”)).
59 Department of Transportation Act of 1966, P.L. 89670, § 6(c)(1), 80 Stat. 938 (1966) (codified as amended at 49
U.S.C. § 40103(b)(1) (2000)).
60 Hillsborough County v. Automated Med. Lab., Inc., 471 U.S. 707, 713 (1985) (quoting Rice v. Santa Fe Elevator
Corp., 331 U.S. 218, 230 (1947)).
61 Id. (quoting Rice, 331 U.S. at 230).





and airport authorities have had limited ability to adopt measures and policies that interfere with 62
the federal government’s ability to control airspace and other aviation related issues.
In addition to the federal preemption statutes, local governments and airport authorities are also
limited by federal law with respect to their ability to raise and spend specific fees and taxes. For
example, taxes and other charges imposed by local governments or airport authorities for use of 63
the facility are generally prohibited by the Anti-Head Tax Act of 1973. Moreover, the Anti-Head
Tax Act prohibits state and/or local governments, and airport authorities from taking other actions 64
that “unreasonably burden and discriminate against interstate commerce.”
The acceptance of federal funding, specifically those awarded out of the Airport Improvement
Fund (AIP), also restricts local authority with respect to aviation issues. Specifically, as a
condition of receiving AIP grant funds, an airport must provide access to its facilities on a
reasonable basis and without discrimination, and must also charge airlines similar prices for 65
similar use. Furthermore, the statute requires that airports accepting AIP funds must undertake 66
efforts to ensure that its rate structure makes the facility “as self-sustaining as possible.”
In City of Burbank v. Lockheed Air Terminal, Inc.,67 the Supreme Court, in an opinion by Justice
Douglas, established what has become known as the “proprietor exception” to the general federal
preemption of local authority with respect to aviation law. In creating this exception, which
reserves some authority for local governments and airport authorities, Justice Douglas appeared
to draw a distinction between municipalities exercising control as proprietors and municipalities 68
exercising police powers in a way that conflicts with federal law.
Since City of Burbank, the lower federal courts have generally held that “an airport proprietor can
issue only ‘reasonable, nonarbitrary, and nondiscriminatory rules that advance the local 69
interest.’” While under this standard courts have upheld regulations aimed at monitoring noise 707172
levels, addressing environmental concerns, and managing ground congestion, there appears

62 See generally, Luis G. Zambrano, Balancing the Rights of Landowners with the Needs of Airports: The Continuing
Battle Over Noise, 66 J. AIR L. & COMM. 445 (2001); see also Ann T. Field & Frances K Davis, Can the Legal Eagles
Use the Ageless Preemption Doctrine to Keep American Aviators Soaring Above the Clouds and into the Twenty-First
Century?, 62 J. AIR L. & COMM. 315 (1997).
63 Anti-Head Tax Act of 1973, P.L. 93-44 § 7(a), 87 Stat. 90 (1973) (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. § 40116(b)
(2000) (expressly prohibitinga State, a political subdivision of a State, and any person that has purchased or leased an
airport from levying or collecting “a tax, fee, head charge, or other charge on: (1) an individual traveling in air
commerce; (2) the transportation of an individual traveling in air commerce; (3) the sale of air transportation; or (4) the
gross receipts from that air commerce or transportation.”).
64 Id. (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. § 40116(d)(2)(A) (2000)).
65 See Airport and Airway Improvement Act of 1982, P.L. 97-248 §§ 503(a)(6), 505(b)(2), 509(b)(1)(E), 511(a)(1)(B),
96 Stat. 673-87 (1982) (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. § 47107(a)(2)(A)-(B) (2000)).
66 Id. (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. 47107(a)(13)(A) (stating thatthe airport owner or operator will maintain a
schedule of charges for use of facilities and services at the airport ... that will make the airport as self-sustaining as
possible under the circumstances existing at the airport, including volume of traffic and economy of collection.).
67 411 U.S. 624, 626 (1973).
68 See id. at 635 n. 14.
69 See American Airlines v. Dep’t of Transp., 202 F.3d 788, 806 (5th Cir. 2000).
70 See Santa Monica Airport Assn v. City of Santa Monica, 659 F.2d 100, 104 (9th Cir. 1981); (limiting the permissible
(continued...)





to be no justification for a broad grant of proprietary power. In 2000, the Fifth Circuit rejected an
interpretation of the proprietor exception that would have permitted an airport owner to “allocate 73
traffic between two airports so as to preserve the short-haul nature of one facility.” It is worth
noting, however, that in the same Fifth Circuit Court of Appeals decision, which involved the
now-repealed “Wright Amendment,” the court did note a willingness to review the exercise of
proprietary powers with respect to advancing previously unrecognized local interests, but not in 74
this particular case. As none of these rulings appear to have addressed the issue of congestion
pricing, it is at best unclear whether such authority is permissible or within the so-called
“proprietor exemption.”
As previously mentioned, there have been two attempts at imposing fee mechanisms that might
be considered “congestion pricing” broadly defined. These attempts both emanated from the local
airport authorities and were met with resistence from adversely affected interests and, in the case
of Boston’s Logan International, from the FAA, primarily on federal preemption grounds. We will
discuss each attempt in turn.
In 1968, the Port Authority of New York and New Jersey, which operates four airports in and
around New York City (LaGuardia (LGA), John F. Kennedy International (JFK), Newark Liberty
International (EWR), and Teterboro (TEB)), sought—“for the purpose of relieving congestion and
achieving the maximum efficient operation at the airports”—to impose a $25 minimum charge for 75
landing during peak hours. The fee applied to any aircraft that took off or landed during the 76
peak hours and had a seating configuration of less than 25 passengers. The fee applies at the
three major Port Authority air-carrier airports, LaGuardia, JFK, and Newark, but not at Teterboro
Airport. A lawsuit was brought on the grounds that the so-called “take-off”fees impermissibly
discriminated in favor of commercial airlines and against general aviation interests.
Plaintiffs argued, inter alia, that the FAA is vested with the sole authority to regulate and control
the national airspace and, therefore, the Port Authority violated federal law in imposing the $25 77
“take-off” fee. In addition to the preemption argument, plaintiffs argued first that the FAA is
required by law to expressly approve of the Port Authority’s regulations, or at a minimum is

(...continued)
subject matter of local regulations to “aircraft noise and other environmental concerns at the local level); see also
British Airways v. Port Authority of New York, 558 F.2d 75, 84 (2d Cir. 1977) (stating that a proprietoris vested only
with the power to promulgate reasonable, non-arbitrary and non-discriminatory regulations that establish acceptable
noise levels for the airport and its immediate environs”).
71 See National Helicopter Corp. of America, 137 F.3d 81, 88-89 (2d Cir. 1998).
72 See Western Air Lines v. Port Authority of New York and New Jersey, 658 F. Supp. 925, 958 (S.D.N.Y. 1986).
73 See American Airlines, 202 F.3d at 807.
74 Id. at 808.
75 See Aircraft Owners and Pilots Assn, v. Port Authority of New York, 305 F.Supp. 93, 98 (D.C.N.Y. 1968).
76 Id. According to the court, the fee apparently had two exceptions, one for helicopters and the other for air taxis
operating pursuant to Port Authority permits. See id.
77 See id. at 104.





required to conform their compatibility with grant and other aid agreements.78 Second, according
to the plaintiffs, “Teterboro is not a reasonably convenient nor adequate facility as an alternate to
the three major New York airports” and, therefore, the diversion of general aviation to Teterboro
would result in a practical exclusion from the New York area airports. Finally, the plaintiffs
asserted a variety of non-legal or policy arguments against the proposal. These arguments
included that it would be ineffective to remedy the airport situation, which was due to over-79
scheduling by commercial airlines and not general aviation, that diversion would not resolve the 80
disparity between airport capacity and demand, and that the record indicated that the
commercial airlines were intimately involved in the proposal and even offered to subsidize
ground transportation from Teterboro to provide further incentive for moving general aviation 81
away from the other airports.
In response to the preemption argument, the court first noted that there exists room “for the
operation of Port Authority Regulations which have the effect of curtailing activities not 82
forbidden by federal regulation.” As a result, according to the court, nothing in the proposed
Port Authority regulations “runs counter to the FAA regulation in the sense that it seeks to
authorize conduct which the federal regulation prohibits or requires the cessation of a practice 83
required by federal regulation.” In response to the argument that the FAA was required to
approve the Port Authority regulations, the court held that there was enough evidence on the 84
record to indicate that there was no “inherent incompatibility” with federal law. Next, the court
addressed the argument that Teterboro is not “reasonably convenient” to New York City. The
court held that Teterboro is “not a nil facility or a purgatorial alternative” and, thus, does provide 85
a valid basis for limiting the Port Authority’s attempts to relieve the region’s congestion. With
respect to the other arguments raised by the plaintiffs, the court found no facts relevant to the
dispute and entered judgment in favor of the defendants, thereby allowing the fees to go into 86
effect.
In 1989, the First Circuit Court of Appeals decided New England Legal Foundation v. 87
Massachusetts Port Authority, which addressed the validity of the landing fee scheme
implemented by the Massachusetts Port Authority (Massport) as part of a multi-phased “Program 88
for Airport Capacity Efficiency (PACE).” The fees at issue were to be a combination of a flat-89
rate landing fee of $91.78 plus a weight-based fee of $0.5417 per 1000 pounds.

78 See id. at 107.
79 See id. at 108.
80 See id. at 109.
81 See id. at 109.
82 Id. at 105.
83 Id.
84 Id. at 107-08.
85 Id. at 108.
86 Id. at 109.
87 883 F.2d 157 (1st Cir. 1989).
88 Id. at 158.
89 Id. at 159.





Several groups that opposed the new landing fee structure filed an administrative complaint with
the FAA alleging that the fees were invalid because they were not “fair and reasonable” and they 90
discriminated against smaller aircraft. The Secretary of the Department of Transportation (DOT)
agreed to review the complaint and commenced an investigation and requested that Massport 91
suspend implementation of PACE. Massport declined and indicated that it would implement the
new fees on July 1, 1988. While the FAA investigation was pending, a separate group filed suit in
federal court seeking declaratory and injunctive relief preventing Massport from implementing 92
the PACE landing fees. In addition, the opposition groups who had sought administrative relief
also filed suits in federal court. All three lawsuits contained similar allegations and were
consolidated. The suits alleged that by shifting the cost burden of the landing fees from the larger
aircraft to the smaller, the new method conflicts with various federal statutes that regulate the 93
national airspace and were therefore preempted. The fees were also alleged to be
constitutionally invalid not only because by placing an undue burden on interstate commerce they 94
violated the Commerce Clause, but also because they discriminated illegally against small
aircraft in contravention of the Equal Protection and Due Process Clauses of the Fourteenth 95
Amendment.
The district court, ruling orally from the bench, found in favor of Massport. On the question of
preemption, the court found that there was no preemption because Congress, in passing the 9697
Airline Deregulation Act of 1978, intended the proprietor to set the landing fees. With respect
to allegations of unreasonableness, the court found that the fees were reasonable because they
were fixed “according to [a] uniform, fair and practical standard ... [and were] non-excessive in
comparison with the governmental benefit conferred” and were “relevant to the operation of the 98
airport ... and fairly consonant with the cost incurred.” Finally, regarding the alleged
discriminatory effect, the court held that “because the objectives of the airport to reduce
congestion and delay are rationally related to legitimate governmental interest ...[the fees]

90 Opponents included the National Business Aircraft Association, the Aircraft Owners and Pilots Association and the
Regional Airline Association. See id. at 160.
91 See id.
92 The New England Legal Foundation filed the suit on behalf of itself as well as the Associated Industries of Vermont,
Eastern Air Charter, Inc., Montair Flight Service, Inc., Ferns Flying Service, Inc., Emerson Aviation, and two business
entities that owned small aircraft using Logan’s facilities. Id. at 160-61.
93 The three statutes cited were the Federal Aviation Act of 1958, the Federal Anti-Head Tax Act, and the Airport and
Airway Improvement Act of 1982. Id. at 161.
94 U.S. CONST. Art. 1, § 8, cl. 3.
95 U.S. CONST. Amend. XIV. It should be noted that the Department of Justice, representing the Department of
Transportation (DOT), filed an amicus curiae brief indicating its interest in the case and suggesting that if the court
could not resolve the issues prior to July 1, 1988, that it issue an injunction preventing the implementation of the PACE
fee structure pending the outcome of the DOT investigation. Id. at 161.
96 Airline Deregulation Act of 1978, P.L. 95-504 § 105(b)(1), 92 Stat 1705 (1978) (codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. §
41713(b)(3) (2000) (stating thatNothing in ... this section shall be construed to limit the authority of any State or
political subdivision thereof or any interstate agency or other political agency of two or more States as the owner or
operator of an airport served by any air carrier certificated by the Board to exercise its proprietary powers and rights.).
97 Id. at 162 (citing Wardair Canada, Inc. v. Florida Department of Revenue, 477 U.S. 1 (1986); Western Airlines, Inc.
v. Port Authority of New York and New Jersey, 817 F.2d 222 (2d Cir. 1987); and Midway Airlines, Inc. v. County of
Westchester, 584 F.Supp. 436 (S.D.N.Y.1984)
98 Id. (citing Evansville—Vanderburgh Airport Authority District v. Delta Airlines, Inc., 405 U.S. 707, 713, 717 (1972);
American Airlines, Inc. v. Massachusetts Port Authority, 560 F.2d 1036, 1039 (1st Cir. 1977)).





enhance economic and operating efficiency” and, therefore, are not discriminatory.99 As a result
of the district court’s ruling, the PACE fee structure went into effect on July 1, 1988.
Litigation then shifted to the DOT, who appointed an Administrative Law Judge (ALJ) to
recommend a decision based on the evidence submitted. The ALJ concluded that the PACE fees
were: (1) in violation of Massport’s grant assurances as they were not “fair and reasonable;” (2) 100
unjustly discriminatory, and were in violation of various federal statutes, and thereby invasive 101
of the DOT’s authority and; (3) preempted by federal law. In addition, to these major findings,
the ALJ also held that Hanscom Field cannot be considered an alternative to Logan International 102
because it “lacks the connecting opportunities that are otherwise available at Logan.” On
appeal to the Secretary of Transportation, the Secretary affirmed and adopted the ALJ’s
recommendations; however, the Secretary indicated that the ALJ “overstated the extent of the
preemptive role of the federal government in the control of airport access and access to the 103
national air transportation system.” According to the Secretary, “it is ... within an airport
proprietor’s authority to impose reasonable [nondiscriminatory,] landing fees or other user fees,
even if such fees may result in a decline in usage by a class of user or other indirect effects on 104
users.” Moreover, “[w]hile an airport sponsor has wide latitude in recovering costs and using
fees to improve the efficient use of airport facilities, the FAA is vested with the authority to 105
control, regulate and manage air traffic.” As a result of the Secretary’s decision, Massport
suspended the PACE fee on December 27, 1988, pending the outcome of its appeal.
Both the district court’s decision and the Secretary’s affirmation of the ALJ’s findings were
appealed to the First Circuit Court of Appeals. The appeals court divided its analysis by statutory
provision. First, the court addressed the allegations that the fees were unreasonable and in
violation of section 511 of the Airport and Airway Improvement Act of 1982. The court affirmed
the Secretary’s determination that the fees were unreasonable on agency deference grounds,
concluding that the record firmly supports the Secretary’s conclusions and that the issue is
“definitely an area of expertise primarily reserved to the Secretary’s discretion, and not to be 106
second-guessed by appellate courts....”
Next, the court reviewed the findings of both the district court and the Secretary with respect to
the Federal Anti-Head Tax Act. The district court had found the fees to be reasonable, thus not in
violation, while the ALJ and ultimately the Secretary had concluded that the fee was not a head-
tax or its equivalent, thus the statute was not implicated. The appeals court upheld both holdings,
though it utilized the rationale provided by the Secretary, concluding that Massport’s fee structure
was “outside the scope of [the act], as not being ... ‘a charge ... on persons traveling in air
commerce,’ nor is it a levy ‘on the carriage of persons’ so traveling, ‘on the sale of air 107
transportation,’ or ‘on the gross receipts derived therefrom.’”

99 Id. at 162.
100 The statutes specifically cited were sections 307 and 105 of the Federal Aviation Act of 1958. Id.
101 Id. at 163.
102 Id.
103 Id. at 165.
104 Id.
105 Id.
106 Id. at 170 (citing Chevron U.S.A. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 467 U.S. 837, 844 (1984); McInnis v.
Weinberger, 530 F.2d 55, 63 (1st Cir. 1976).
107 Id. at 170 (citing 49 U.S.C. App. § 1513 (1988) re-codified as amended at 49 U.S.C. § 40116 (2000)).





Finally, the appeals court addressed the preemption issues raised by sections 105 and 307 of the
Federal Aviation Act of 1958 as amended. On this issue the district court and the Secretary had
disagreed, with the court finding the fees reasonable and hence not preempted, while the
Secretary found them to be unreasonable and, therefore, preempted by federal law. The appeals
court ultimately concluded that the district court erred “not only in its decision, but also in not
deferring to the Secretary’s primary jurisdiction over this controversy as was requested by the
DOT in its last minute amicus intercession.” Relying on the doctrine of “primary jurisdiction” the
court held that in cases such as these “[w]hen there is a basis for judicial action, independent of
agency proceedings, courts may route the threshold decisions as to certain issues to the agency
charged with primary responsibility for governmental supervision or control of the particular 108
industry or activity involved.” In other words, the district court should have deferred its
judgment until after the FAA and the Secretary had investigated and completed their
administrative review. Turning to the merits of the Secretary’s decision, the court concluded that
Massport’s fee structure was an impermissible interference with air navigation and, therefore, 109
preempted by federal law. Having decided the case on statutory grounds, the court declined to 110
address the constitutional issues raised by the Commerce Clause or the Fourteenth Amendment.
Based on these two cases it is difficult to discern precisely where the courts are with respect to
airport imposed pricing mechanisms intended to relieve congestion. At one level it seems that
perhaps the different results reached turned on the availability and feasibility of alternative
landing sites for the smaller general aviation planes that were adversely affected by both pricing
schemes. In the case of New York and Teterboro, the court found that to be a viable alternative,
whereas with respect to Boston and Hanscom the ALJ was not persuaded that the alternative
location was reasonable. Resting on this distinction, however, appears to oversimplify many of
the complex issues that the court and the ALJ dealt with in the Massport case. The development
of aviation law and addition of new statutes in the 20 years between the two cases appeared to
play an integral role in the difference between the results. Currently, the law remains nearly
identical to what it was in Massport, thereby making it unlikely that another attempt by a local
airport authority to impose a similar pricing scheme without the FAA’s express approval would 111
succeed. Admittedly, this analysis appears to render the fees at LaGuardia sui generis; however,
such a conclusion appears to be a reasonable way to reconcile what on their face seem to be two
irreconcilable judicial decisions. That said, it does not appear to be per se impossible for local
airport authorities to take action. It may be that a fee structure could be developed that imposes
fees—designed to reduce congestion—that are reasonable, non-discriminatory, and based on the
airport’s historical operating costs. Assuming such a fee structure could be developed, it appears
possible that it may not be in violation of either federal law or FAA regulations.

108 Id. at 171 (citing Port of Boston Marine Terminal Assn v. Rederiaktiebolaget Transatlantic, 400 U.S. 62, 68 (1970);
see also United States v. Western Pacific R. Co., 352 U.S. 59, 63-65 (1956); Far Eastern Conf. v. United States, 342
U.S. 570, 573-75 (1952)).
109 Id. at 175 (stating thatthe actions of Massport under its new landing fee scheme are even more clearly prohibited
by this provision as an interference with air navigation”).
110 Id. at 176 (stating that “in keeping with longstanding precedent that requires us to avoid ruling on constitutional
issues when non-constitutional grounds are dispositive, we shall not pass upon the questions raised dealing with alleged
independent violations of the Interstate Commerce Clause and the Equal Protection and Due Process Clauses.).
111 Meaning of its own kind/genus or unique in its characteristics. See BLACKS LAW DICTIONARY, 1448 (7th Ed. 1999).





As the previous section indicated, all of the prior attempts at imposing congestion pricing
mechanisms have been locally generated by the airport authorities. Neither the FAA nor the DOT
have, to date, attempted to develop and impose a congestion pricing scheme on the local
authorities. In the event that FAA should decide to make such an attempt, it appears that there are
several legal issues that may arise.
First, there appears to be a question of legal authority. Does FAA have the legal authority to
impose such a system without a change in the current statutes? Based on a review of the statutes
currently in place, it appears that the FAA has a reasonable basis to proceed. While it is true that
there is no specific statute that directly provides FAA with such authority, an argument can be
made that, by virtue of the agency’s statutory mandate with respect to the airspace of the United
States, the legal authority exists. Phrased another way, if the FAA characterizes the imposition of
a congestion pricing scheme as an “airspace,” “air traffic,” or “air navigation” means of managing
it may be argued that it would fall within the agency’s existing authority provided by Congress to
“develop plans and policy for the use of the navigable airspace and assign by regulation or order
the use of the airspace necessary to ensure the safety of aircraft and the efficient use of 112
airspace.” This argument would also appear to be consistent with the Secretary’s finding in 113
Massport that the “FAA is vested with the authority to control, regulate and manage air traffic.”
Yet another way of looking at this is potentially through a “negative preemption” type 114
argument. In other words, if, as the DOT argued in Massport, the local airport authorities are
preempted by federal law from imposing unreasonable and/or discriminatory fees—even to
reduce congestion—then it stands to reason that the federal government, through the FAA, is the
only place where such a regulation could originate.
In addition, it should be noted that there appears to be a generally-applicable federal statute that
permits the heads of agencies to “prescribe regulations establishing the charge for a service or 115
thing of value provided by the agency.” The statute requires that each charge “shall be: (1) fair;
and (2) based on—(A) the costs to the Government; (B) the value of the service or thing to the 116
recipient; (C) public policy or interest served; and (D) other relevant facts.” The Supreme
Court has held that this authority extends to “only specific charges for specific services to specific 117
individuals or companies.” Based on the plain language of this statute, it appears possible for
the FAA to assert that the “thing of value” provided is access to the national airspace; therefore,
imposing fees and charges, provided they meet the requirements of the statute, is arguably
permissible. Although it does not appear that this statute has ever been used with respect to fees
relating to airspace use, during its existence the Civil Aeronautics Board did use the statute to

112 Department of Transportation Act of 1966, P.L. 89670, § 6(c)(1), 80 Stat. 938 (1966) (codified as amended at 49
U.S.C. § 40103(b)(1) (2000)).
113 Massport, 883 F.2d at 165.
114Negative preemption” occurs in cases where the state and/or local authorities are prohibited from regulating even
where the responsible federal agency is silent. See, e.g., Susan J. Stabile, Preemption of State Law by Federal Law: A
Question for Congress or the Courts?, 40 VILL. L. REV. 1, 6-7 (1995) (citing Arkansas Elec. Coop. Corp. v. Arkansas
Pub. Serv. Commn, 461 U.S. 375, 384 (1983); Ray v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 435 U.S. 151, 178 (1978); Machinists v.
Wisconsin Employment Relations Commn, 427 U.S. 132 (1975)).
115 Independent Offices Appropriation Act of 1952, P.L. 137, § 501, 65 Stat. 268, 290 (1958) (codified as amended at
31 U.S.C. § 9701 (2000)).
116 Id.
117 Federal Power Com’n v. New England Power Co., 415 U.S. 345, 349 (1974).





impose and modify various filing and licensing fees,118 so its use in the aviation context is not
without precedent.
A second question that arises has to do with the idea of reasonableness and non-discrimination in
setting airport fees. If one accepts the authority argument that only the FAA can impose a
congestion pricing system, it appears to follow then that the restrictions currently in place that
prohibit state and local authorities from discriminating and imposing unreasonable fees would not
apply, as the pricing scheme would be federally imposed and not locally mandated. Similarly,
none of the AIP restrictions on local airport authorities appear to be implicated by an FAA
imposed congestion pricing scheme. A more complicated set of questions arise should the FAA
decide not to impose congestion pricing directly, but rather to delegate the authority to impose
congestion pricing to various local airport authorities. In this situation, it would appear that either
FAA would have to waive the restrictions on reasonableness and non-discrimination or simply
refuse to enforce the potential violations that may ensue from implementation of its mandate. 119
Based on a plain reading of both the Anti-Head Tax and the Airport and Airway Improvement 120
Act of 1982, neither statute appears to provide the Secretary or the Administrator of the FAA
with the authority to grant waivers for states to levy taxes, or from the non-discrimination and
reasonableness requirements. In fact, the Airport and Airway Improvement Act of 1982 seems to
require that approval be granted “only if the Secretary receives written assurances, satisfactory to
the Secretary, that ... the airport will be available for public use on reasonable conditions and 121
without unjust discrimination.” Hence, it would appear that should the FAA attempt to delegate
its authority over a potential congestion pricing scheme to the local airport authorities, it will first
have to seek a statutory change from Congress.
A third question arises with respect to the use of any funds collected from the imposition of a
federally mandated congestion pricing scheme. Even if it is accepted that FAA has the legal
authority to implement a congestion pricing scheme it does not automatically follow that the FAA
or the DOT would be permitted to retain the fees collected. It is a generally accepted principle of
federal appropriations law that absent statutory authority to the contrary, the “miscellaneous 122
receipts statute” requires agencies to deposit funds received for the government into the federal
Treasury, otherwise known as the “general fund.” An agency may only retain such moneys it
receives if it has statutory authority to do so. According to decisions of the Comptroller General,
the “miscellaneous receipts statute” does not apply if there is specific statutory authority for the 123
agency to retain the funds. Consequently, absent such specific authority, it would appear that
even if the FAA were to delegate congestion pricing authority to the local airport authorities, the
money would still be required to go to the Treasury’s “general fund.” This conclusion follows
from principles of delegation; namely, that government entities cannot delegate authority that 124
they themselves do not possess. Hence, if FAA does not possess the authority to keep the fees
that it collects from a congestion pricing scheme, it cannot properly delegate the power to keep
the fees to a local airport authority. In sum, should it be desired that the funds collected from a
congestion pricing mechanism go anywhere but the “general fund,” Congress will have to pass a

118 See Air Transport Ass’n of America v. C.A.B., 732 F.2d 219, 221 (D.C. Cir. 1984).
119 49 U.S.C. § 40116 (2000).
120 49 U.S.C. § 47107 (2000).
121 Id. at (a)(2) (emphasis added).
122 31 U.S.C. § 3302(b) (2000).
123 See, e.g., 72 Comp. Gen. 164, 16566 (1993).
124 See, e.g., Northern Pipeline Constr. Co. v. Marathon Pipe Line Co., 458 U.S. 50 (1982).





statute authorizing the retention and expenditures of the funds. Similarly, it appears that any
expenditures of funds collected will have to be specifically authorized and appropriated by 125
Congress.
Bart Elias John W. Fischer
Specialist in Aviation Policy Specialist in Transportation Policy
belias@crs.loc.gov, 7-7771 jfischer@crs.loc.gov, 7-7766
Todd B. Tatelman
Legislative Attorney
ttatelman@crs.loc.gov, 7-4697


125 See 31 U.S.C. § 1341 (2000) (prohibiting the expenditure of federal funds without express authorization by
Congress).